Abstract

Background: There is universal agreement that higher mortality goes with lower income. Opinions differ on causality: the association may reflect the damaging effect of poverty on health and survival chances. Conversely, it may reflect selection/reverse causation: low income indicates health problems, and from health problems follow a higher risk of dying. Methods: We studied all deaths in Norway (111 504) during the 10-year period 1994–2003 among persons aged 25–66 years in 1993 (2 261 076). For each year, age-standardized mortality rates were calculated for each 1993 income decile for men and women separately. Income was calculated as family size-adjusted income after taxes but including cash welfare transfers. If the selection theory was correct, one would expect to see the excess mortality in the lower income fractiles decline as the bad risks, over-represented among the poorer, died away. Results: Large income decile variations in mortality remained at the end of the 10-year period: after 10 years, the age-standardized mortality rate for men and women was still much higher in the lower income deciles. Conclusion: As the excess mortality in the poorer income deciles was not much reduced during the 10-year period, excess mortality among persons in bad health in the lower income deciles does not explain the income inequality in mortality in our data set.

Introduction

Health problems and increased mortality have consistently been shown to co-vary with income and socio-economic position: the more privileged have lower morbidity and mortality.1–4 The relationship has even been demonstrated in the relatively well-to-do and egalitarian societies with an advanced welfare state with universal health service coverage and high cash transfers, like the Nordic countries.5–8 Cash welfare benefits in Norway include—time-limited—sickness benefits and unemployment benefits, compensating for loss of income during sickness and absences from work and during periods of unemployment and disability benefits—permanent: once granted, they keep running until replaced by the general old-age pension when one reaches 67 years of age. Not part of the cash transfer system, but still relevant to the income gradient in mortality, is the fact that health care is not a big threat to the economy of those who fall ill: hospital care is free for all, and there are upper limits to what must be paid for primary health care and medications (in 2011, not more than NOK 1880 (∼310 US$ or 230 €)). Co-payment for nursing home care is upwardly restricted to 75% of the national old-age pension and 85% of other income, and does not dig into the institutionalized persons’ bank accounts or the value of their home or other assets. Still, the income inequality in mortality may even be increasing in western Europe,9 as well as in Norway.10

On the question of the causal link between income and mortality, however, opinions differ strongly: do we see causation or selection? Unprivileged living may be bad for health. With fewer material resources at hand, one may end up with worse housing, in less healthy neighbourhoods, too little food or unhealthy food, etc., or, at least, in a position of relative deprivation and a stressing feeling of dissatisfaction with life.1,4

A strong statement to the effect that inequalities in health follow from social inequalities was presented by the 2010 Marmot Review.11 However, the possible causal connection may also go the other way. The relationship of income to health may be produced by reverse causation. Among the materially underprivileged are many who have been sick for a while and who have had to change to part-time working or drop out of work completely. Excess mortality in lower income fractiles therefore is not necessarily caused by the socio-economic circumstances of low-income earners. It may also reflect the sedimentation of unhealthier people, who run a higher risk of dying earlier, into the bottom layers of the income distribution, and, as shown by Fox, Goldblatt and Jones,12 the lower occupational classes contained disproportionate numbers of unemployed, sick or early retired persons. Additionally, as shown in the literature review by Palloni, Milesi, White and Turner,13 many14–24 have argued that at least partly the observed SES gradients are the outcome of selection mechanisms, whereby individuals in poor health early in life are more likely to experience downward mobility. In reaction to the Marmot Review, Chandra and Vogel25 pointed out that selection complicates the interpretation of the relationship of health to income, and Canning and Bowser26 argued in favour of viewing “the socio-economic gradient in health to be large part the result of differentials in health, reversing the direction of causality put forward in the Marmot reports”. Analyses of Norwegian data have concluded in the same direction. Rognerud and Zahl10 have argued that their results may indicate reverse causation: poor health caused low income, more strongly in 1997 than in 1970. Data from the Nord-Trøndelag health surveys28 have been interpreted along the same lines: the increased mortality of men of the lowest income quartile might be explained by life course development of health inequalities.

This article, limited to direct intragenerational selection, follows the income gradient in sex- and age-standardized mortality rates for the years 1994–2003, to see whether it flattened during the 10-year period, as would be expected from the selection hypothesis. We study all deaths in the entire Norwegian population aged 25–66 years in 1993 for the 10-year period 1994–2003. If the selection explanation holds, one would expect to see the excess mortality in the lower income fractiles petering out as the bad risks among the poorer die away, reducing their over-representation among the less well-to-do.

Methods

The data set was derived from official Norwegian administrative registers including the entire Norwegian population, and known for their completeness and data quality. Missing data are infrequent. In this study, the most common piece of missing information was vital status, which was unavailable for 1.4% of the men and women in the selected age span. The most common cause of missing data was emigration.

Data from the different registers were linked by means of the personal identification number and have been made available for the project by the Norwegian Social Science Data Service and Statistics Norway.29 To limit the study to that part of the population that had the chance of being occupationally active at the start of the period studied, we included in our analysis persons aged 25–66 years who were alive at the end of 1993 and whose vital status could be followed through 2003. The reason for excluding those under 25 was that many of them were students of low present income but on their way to well-paid jobs. The reason for excluding those over 66 was that Norwegians are entitled to old-age pension from the age of 67 years; among those over 66, the overwhelming majority are pensioners.

For each year during 1994–2003, the fraction who died during that year (of those who were alive at the beginning of the year) was calculated for each sex and each 6-year age group in each income decile (the age span of 25–66 years divides into seven 6-year intervals). The age-adjusted mortality rates of the highest income decile served as our point of reference. From these death rates was calculated, for each year and for each sex separately, the number of deaths to be expected in each age group in each of the lower income deciles if they had had the age group-specific death rate of the highest income decile. To show the excess mortality of each lower income decile, we then calculated for each year the standardized mortality ratio of each decile as the ratio of the observed number of deaths for that year in that income decile to the number of deaths to be expected from the age group-specific death rates of those in the highest income decile.

Changes in mortality trends were analysed using Cochran–Armitage test for time trends. It is similar to a crude chi-squared test, but it is more sensitive to the linearity between response variables and experimental variables and detects smaller changes that would not be noticeable using more crude methods. Mortality ratios were already adjusted for age groups and sex; therefore, there was no need to use a model-based method for assessing a trend.

To avoid misclassifying as poor married/cohabiting persons with no or low personal income—particularly married/cohabiting women, whose economic position is not well described by their own earnings—we calculated for each person not his/her personal income, but the income of the household to which they belonged. The same income will mean different levels of living for households of different sizes, and we adjusted post-tax household income for household size by the fairly common procedure30–32 of dividing the net amount calculated as described earlier by the square root of the number of family members.

Income was measured as family size-adjusted net 1993 income. As the Norwegian welfare system is fairly comprehensive, and the tax system is fairly progressive, income was measured after the inclusion of welfare cash transfers and after taxes. To calculate a family’s total taxable income, we summed all forms of income received in 1993 (wages, income from own business enterprise(s), bank account interests, profits from shares, etc., as well as all welfare cash payments received) by all members of the family (linked by the family’s unique number).

From the family’s total taxable income was deducted the sum of taxes paid by all members of the family, to produce an income figure reflecting the actual level of income at hand for the family, more closely related to the family’s standard of living than its gross sum of earnings.

The average family size-adjusted net 1993 income for 25–66-year-old men was 173 227 NOK (∼30 000 US$ or 22 000 €)—the range was 0–68 million (∼0–12 million US$ or 0–8.5 million €). Figures for women were about the same: average = 165 039 NOK (28 000 US$/20 000 €), range = 0–67 million (11 million US$/8 million €). The number of very rich was low; the highest family size-adjusted net income decile started at 249 419 NOK for men and 239 353 NOK for women—for both sexes ∼1.4 times the average family size-adjusted net 1993 income of Norwegian men and women aged 25-66 years.

The total number of persons aged 25–66 years alive at the start of 1994, of whom we had information on vital status through 2003 and on sex and net 1993 income (adjusted for family size), was 2 197 683—1 111 305 men and 1 086 378 women. The total number of deaths during 1994–2003 among Norwegians born in 1927–68 (aged 25–66 years old in 1993) was 102 696 (47 per thousand of those alive at the start of 1994). The distribution of deaths by year for each sex and the number of persons alive at the start of each year are shown in table 1.

Table 1

Persons born in 1927–1968 who were alive at the beginning of each year during 1994–2003, number of deaths each year, by sex

YearMales
Females
Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)
19941 111 3055001 (4.50)1 086 3782720 (2.51)
19951 106 3045349 (4.84)1 083 6582896 (2.67)
19961 100 9555462 (4.96)1 080 7623178 (2.94)
19971 095 4935483 (5.01)1 077 7643386 (3.14)
19981 089 6506358 (5.83)1 074 1983578 (3.33)
19991 083 2926674 (6.16)1 070 6203913 (3.65)
20001 076 6186906 (6.42)1 066 7074219 (3.96)
20011 069 7127240 (6.77)1 062 4884479 (4.22)
20021 062 4727800 (7.34)1 058 0094908 (4.64)
20031 054 6727997 (7.58)1 053 1015149 (4.89)
Sum of deaths 1994–200364 270 (57.89 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)38 426 (35.37 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)
YearMales
Females
Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)
19941 111 3055001 (4.50)1 086 3782720 (2.51)
19951 106 3045349 (4.84)1 083 6582896 (2.67)
19961 100 9555462 (4.96)1 080 7623178 (2.94)
19971 095 4935483 (5.01)1 077 7643386 (3.14)
19981 089 6506358 (5.83)1 074 1983578 (3.33)
19991 083 2926674 (6.16)1 070 6203913 (3.65)
20001 076 6186906 (6.42)1 066 7074219 (3.96)
20011 069 7127240 (6.77)1 062 4884479 (4.22)
20021 062 4727800 (7.34)1 058 0094908 (4.64)
20031 054 6727997 (7.58)1 053 1015149 (4.89)
Sum of deaths 1994–200364 270 (57.89 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)38 426 (35.37 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)
Table 1

Persons born in 1927–1968 who were alive at the beginning of each year during 1994–2003, number of deaths each year, by sex

YearMales
Females
Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)
19941 111 3055001 (4.50)1 086 3782720 (2.51)
19951 106 3045349 (4.84)1 083 6582896 (2.67)
19961 100 9555462 (4.96)1 080 7623178 (2.94)
19971 095 4935483 (5.01)1 077 7643386 (3.14)
19981 089 6506358 (5.83)1 074 1983578 (3.33)
19991 083 2926674 (6.16)1 070 6203913 (3.65)
20001 076 6186906 (6.42)1 066 7074219 (3.96)
20011 069 7127240 (6.77)1 062 4884479 (4.22)
20021 062 4727800 (7.34)1 058 0094908 (4.64)
20031 054 6727997 (7.58)1 053 1015149 (4.89)
Sum of deaths 1994–200364 270 (57.89 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)38 426 (35.37 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)
YearMales
Females
Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)Alive at start of yearDied during the year (per 1000)
19941 111 3055001 (4.50)1 086 3782720 (2.51)
19951 106 3045349 (4.84)1 083 6582896 (2.67)
19961 100 9555462 (4.96)1 080 7623178 (2.94)
19971 095 4935483 (5.01)1 077 7643386 (3.14)
19981 089 6506358 (5.83)1 074 1983578 (3.33)
19991 083 2926674 (6.16)1 070 6203913 (3.65)
20001 076 6186906 (6.42)1 066 7074219 (3.96)
20011 069 7127240 (6.77)1 062 4884479 (4.22)
20021 062 4727800 (7.34)1 058 0094908 (4.64)
20031 054 6727997 (7.58)1 053 1015149 (4.89)
Sum of deaths 1994–200364 270 (57.89 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)38 426 (35.37 per thousand alive at beginning of 1994)

Results

Men

As shown in figure 1, during the 10-year period, male excess mortality in the lower income deciles (relative to the richest decile, decile 10) was reduced (Cochran–Armitage test for trends, P < 0.001). Still, large differences remained at the end of the period. The picture was practically the same for men aged 25–42 and 61–66 years as for all men in our data file (graphs not shown). Table 2 provides the same picture: the variation coefficient (VC) of decile SMRs for men was lower in 2003 than in 1994, but large differences remained at the end of the period.

Decile 1 = poorest decile, Decile 10 = richest decile. Y-axis shows the ratio (multiplied by 100) of the expected to the observed number of deaths in each income decile; were the deciles to have the same mortality rates as the richest income decile in each (6-year) age group
Figure 1

Decile 1 = poorest decile, Decile 10 = richest decile. Y-axis shows the ratio (multiplied by 100) of the expected to the observed number of deaths in each income decile; were the deciles to have the same mortality rates as the richest income decile in each (6-year) age group

Table 2

Standard deviation (SD) and VC of decile SMRs, by gender and year

Year1994199519961997199819992000200120022003
Men aged 25–66 years
    SD71696063666358506054
    VC0.420.420.400.400.400.370.370.330.380.35
Women aged 25–66 years
    SD43394244434638563842
    VC0.310.300.310.300.290.320.270.330.270.29
Year1994199519961997199819992000200120022003
Men aged 25–66 years
    SD71696063666358506054
    VC0.420.420.400.400.400.370.370.330.380.35
Women aged 25–66 years
    SD43394244434638563842
    VC0.310.300.310.300.290.320.270.330.270.29
Table 2

Standard deviation (SD) and VC of decile SMRs, by gender and year

Year1994199519961997199819992000200120022003
Men aged 25–66 years
    SD71696063666358506054
    VC0.420.420.400.400.400.370.370.330.380.35
Women aged 25–66 years
    SD43394244434638563842
    VC0.310.300.310.300.290.320.270.330.270.29
Year1994199519961997199819992000200120022003
Men aged 25–66 years
    SD71696063666358506054
    VC0.420.420.400.400.400.370.370.330.380.35
Women aged 25–66 years
    SD43394244434638563842
    VC0.310.300.310.300.290.320.270.330.270.29

Women

As shown in figure 1, during the 10-year period, female excess mortality (relative to the richest decile, decile 10) was not reduced (Cochran–Armitage test for trends, P = 0.15): large differences remained at the end of the period. The picture was practically the same for women aged 25–42 and 61–66 years as for all women in our data file (graphs not shown). Table 2 provides the same picture: the VC of decile SMRs for women was practically the same in 2003 as in 1994.

Discussion

The excess mortality of the lower income deciles did decrease somewhat, but not much, during the 10-year period 1994–2003. A possible interpretation is that individuals with bad health and higher risks of dying were over-represented in the lowest 1993 income deciles. As they die, the excess mortality should go down. The trend, however, was rather weak for men, and not significant for women. For both genders, large differences in mortality by income remained at the end of the period. The selection interpretation that the SMRs would tend to converge over time was hardly supported by our data, as SMR differences between the income deciles, for both genders, were only slightly reduced during the 10-year period and were substantial also in 2003. As shown in figure 1, the SMR for the lowest income decile in 2001 (men) and 2002 (women) deviated considerably from the overall trend. In an attempt to explain this, we have both checked the data for errors and examined whether special events occurred during those years, but we are not able to provide any plausible explanation for these fluctuations.

A strength of the analysis is the fact that it followed the mortality of the entire 1993 Norwegian population of persons born in 1927–1968, and that we controlled the income differences in mortality for sex and age. Sub-analyses for the younger (25–42 years) and the older (61–66 years) persons of the data set did not deviate from the results for the entire population. Also, we studied the effect of income after it has been adjusted for household size, not falling into the trap of considering as equal, a certain amount of earned money regardless of how many persons shall live off it. We also used net income, after taxes and welfare transfers, thus avoiding the risk of accepting at face value, high nominational incomes, which will be reduced by progressive taxation before the income earner and his/her dependants can start enjoying it.

A number of limitations must, however, be pointed out. First, we have only followed our subjects for 10 years, and the possibility that the mortality experiences of the income deciles will in the longer run conform to what is predicted by the selection hypothesis of reverse causation cannot be dismissed on the basis of our data: 10 years of follow-up may be too little.

Another important limitation is that we only have income data for 1 year (1993). We do not know whether that income year was typical or atypical for our individuals and households. Persons earning a lot in 1993 may have earned little in the years before or after (or vice versa), so that their true position in the national income hierarchy may not be well described by their 1993 income. Also, we lack data on material resources other than taxable income: having a social network and including a car mechanic, a dentist and a plumber may have considerable unregistered cash value. One may also worry that official income data may not accurately reflect true income—being taxation data, they may be coloured by an unknown degree of both fraudulent tax evasion and legal deductions. Such data inaccuracies will have the effect of narrowing the income distribution and attenuating the mortality differences between the income deciles. Norwegian tax authorities, however, are reputed to have a fairly accurate income registration system.

On the more technical side, it should be mentioned that the population data were only 98.6% complete. The most common cause of missing data was emigration. This may be a relevant source of error in this context: if old and sick immigrants go home to die, mortality in their income deciles is reduced. Immigrants are lower earners: in our data set, the average immigrant household income was 82% of the non-immigrant household income. This may mean that a selection bias has reduced income-related mortality differences. On the other hand, Norway did not have a large immigrant population in 1993; in our data set, only 5.4% were first-generation immigrants; the immigrants were slightly younger than the native Norwegians (on average 40.4 years in 1993, native Norwegian average 1993 age was 43.1 years), and no one in our data set was older than 66 years in 1993.

Also, our data on household size are imperfect. The official data registers that produced our data did provide a unique family number for each individual. However, that number cannot be trusted to identify 100% correctly the actual household in which the person lived in 1993. The question of how to count grown-up children who—perhaps temporarily like students—do not live at home with their parents is unsolved. Additionally, as the cohabitation of couples not being formally married gets more common, the problem of identifying households correctly is growing. Grouping people into households by their official family numbers may include among the true low-decile earners, people who do not belong there. Mixing the real low earners with cohabiting couples whose incomes should have been pooled and whose living expenses are reduced by not having to maintain two separate households may have had the effect of underestimating the income decile mortality differences. The same can be said for parents of students who have left their childhood home but are still formally registered as living with their parents.

Much of the research into the socio-economic gradient in mortality—in particular English research—has studied health-based selection into occupational classes I–V, and not health-based selection into income groups. Our data only allowed us to look into the income gradient in mortality. The mechanism of health selection effect into income deciles may differ from the health-based selection into occupational classes.

It should also be borne in mind that our data set consisted of persons aged 25–66 years in 1993, i.e. born 1927–68, whom we followed for 10 years. We had no data on their position earlier in life. Our conclusions therefore refer only to the relationship of mortality to adult income, and can say nothing about the effects of life course selection on the basis of possible early formative experiences. Neither did we have data on intergenerational mobility, but we can only speak on intragenerational direct health selection.

The income effect of bad health may be smaller in Norway than in other countries. In the Norwegian welfare state, even a serious health problem does not ruin a person’s economy. Government-financed health care offers free hospital treatment, and the welfare system cash transfers ensures that disabled persons do not slide into poverty if they must give up their job. In an international perspective, the selection into lower income deciles of persons in bad health may therefore be less pronounced in the Nordic welfare states than in many other countries.

The most important caveat, however, is that finding that the excess mortality in the lower income fractiles did not decline much during the 10 years studied is not tantamount to proving the selection theory wrong. Early excess mortality among the poorer might be effects of long-term exposure to the disadvantages of low income and/or bad health followed by reductions in income. One might even argue that because of an income effect on health, people die; therefore, the effect of social causation wears off with time. As stated earlier, we only had income data for 1 year. Also, we had no baseline health data, and are therefore unable to entangle whether excessive deaths are due to selection or causation—most likely both processes are operative.

Funding

The project was supported by a grant from the Norwegian Research Council [Project number 163970/V50].

Conflicts of interest: None declared.

Key points

  • The current article tests one of the implications of the selection/reverse causation explanations of the social gradient in health: if bad risks die earlier, the excess mortality of the poorer income deciles will wear off over the years.

  • Selection was not a strong explanation of the higher death risk in the lower income deciles, at least not in the context of the affluent Norwegian welfare state. During the 10-year period studied, the age- and sex-adjusted mortality rates of the poorer income deciles did not sink much towards the mortality rate of the richest decile.

  • Policies to reduce economic inequalities may be relevant to public health and should not be discarded on the basis of the idea that the income gradient in mortality merely reflects the selection of bad risks into the lower income deciles.

Acknowledgements

Anonymized data were provided by Statistics Norway and the Norwegian Social Science Data Services. Neither is responsible for the analysis of the data and the interpretations presented.

Preliminary results from these analyses were presented and discussed at the ISIG (International Study of Income Gradients in Health) research group meeting in San Francisco, 6–8 September 2010.

Before the anonymized data was sent to us for analysis, our research plan was approved by the relevant government institutions: the Norwegian Data Inspectorate (Datatilsynet) and the Governmental Board of Health (Helsetilsynet), which decided that the research plan did not impinge on patient and citizen rights to anonymity and privacy.

References

1
Townsend
P
Davidson
N
Inequalities in Health: The Black Report
,
1982
London
Penguin Books
2
Mackenbach
J
,
Health inequalities: Europe in profile. An independent, expert report commissioned by the UK Presidency of the EU
,
2006
 
3
Kunst
A
Bos
V
Lahelma
E
et al.
,
Trends in socioeconomic inequalities in self-assessed health in 10 European countries
Int J Epidemiol
,
2005
, vol.
34
(pg.
295
-
305
)
4
Wilkinson
R
Pickett
K
The Spirit Level: Why Equality Is Better for Everyone
,
2010
London
Penguin Books
5
Dahl
E
Kjærsgaard
P
,
Trends in socio-economic mortality differentials in post-war Norway—evidence and interpretations
Sociol Health Illness
,
1993
, vol.
14
(pg.
447
-
71
)
6
Borgan
J
,
Socio-economic trends in differential mortality among middle-aged males in Norway 1960-1990
In: Yearbook of Population Research in Finland
,
1996
Helsinki
The Population Institute
7
Zahl
P
Rognerud
M
Strand
B
Tverdal
Å
Bedre helse—større forskjeller [Improved health—larger differences]
,
2003
Oslo
Nasjonalt folkehelseinstitutt [National Institute of Public Health]
 
Rapport 2003:1
8
Lahelma
E
Martikainen
P
Laaksonen
M
Aittomäki
A
,
Pathways between socioeconomic determinants of health
J Epidemiol Community Health
,
2004
, vol.
58
(pg.
327
-
32
)
9
Mackenbach
J
Bos
V
Anderson
O
et al.
,
Widening socioecomic inequalities in mortality in six Western European countries
Int J Epidemiol
,
2003
, vol.
32
(pg.
830
-
7
)
10
Rognerud
M
Zahl
P
,
Social inequalities in mortality: changes in the relative importance of income, education and household size over a 27-year period
Eur J Public Health
,
2005
, vol.
16
(pg.
62
-
8
)
11
Marmot Review
,
Fair society, healthy lives: strategic review of health inequalities in England post
,
2010
London
Marmot Review
 
12
Fox
A
Goldblatt
P
Jones
D
Wilkinson
RG
,
Social class mortality differentials: artefact, selection, or life circumstances?
Class and Health. Research and Longitudinal Data
,
1986
London
Tavistock Publications
(pg.
34
-
49
)
13
Palloni
A
Milesi
C
White
R
Turner
A
,
Early childhood health, reproduction of economic inequalities and the persistence of health and mortality differentials
Soc Sci Med
,
2009
, vol.
68
(pg.
1574
-
82
)
14
Grossman
M
,
On the concept of health capital and the demand for health
J Polit Econ
,
1972
, vol.
80
(pg.
223
-
55
)
15
Fox
A
Goldblatt
P
Adelstein
A
,
Selection and mortality differentials
J Epidemiol Community Health
,
1982
, vol.
36
(pg.
369
-
95
)
16
Stern
J
,
Social mobility and interpretation of social class mortality differentials
J Soc Policy
,
1983
, vol.
12
(pg.
27
-
49
)
17
West
P
,
Rethinking the health selection explanation for health inequalities
Soc Sci Med
,
1991
, vol.
32
(pg.
373
-
84
)
18
Bartley
M
Plewis
I
,
Does health-selective mobility account for socioeconomic differences in health? Evidence from England and Wales 1971-1991
J Health Soc Behav
,
1997
, vol.
38
(pg.
376
-
86
)
19
Power
C
Matthews
S
Manor
O
,
Inequalities in self-rated health: explanations from different stages of life
Lancet
,
1998
, vol.
351
(pg.
1584
-
9
)
20
Blane
D
Harding
S
Rosato
M
,
Does social mobility affect the size of the socioeconomic mortality differential? Evidence from the Office for National Statistics Longitudinal Study
J R Stat Soc Ser A Stat Soc
,
1999
, vol.
162
(pg.
59
-
70
)
21
Blane
D
Davey Smith
G
Hart
C
,
Some social and physical correlates of intergenerational social mobility: evidence from the West of Scotland collaborative study
Sociology
,
1999
, vol.
33
(pg.
169
-
83
)
22
Smith
J
,
Healthy bodies and thick wallets: the dual relationship between health and economic status
J Econ Perspect
,
1999
, vol.
13
(pg.
145
-
66
)
23
Smith
J
,
Unraveling the SES-health connection
Popul Dev Rev
,
2004
, vol.
30
(pg.
108
-
32
Supplement: Aging, Health and Public Policy: Demographic and Economic Perspectives
24
Manor
O
Matthews
S
Power
C
,
Health selection: the role of inter- and intra-generational mobility in social inequalities in health
Soc Sci Med
,
2003
, vol.
57
(pg.
2217
-
27
)
25
Chandra
A
Vogl
T
,
Rising up with the shoe leather? A comment on Fair Society, Healthy Lives (the Marmot Review)
Soc Sci Med
,
2010
, vol.
71
(pg.
1227
-
30
)
26
Canning
D
Bowser
D
,
Investing in health to improve the wellbeing of the disadvantaged: reversing the argument of Fair Society, Healthy Lives (the Marmot Review)
Soc Sci Med
,
2010
, vol.
71
(pg.
1223
-
6
)
27
Sundt
E
Om fattigforholdene i Christiania [On poverty in Christiania, Norway]
,
1978
Oslo
Gyldendal
28
Skalicka
V
van Lenthe
F
Bambra
C
et al.
,
Material, psychosocial, behavioural and biomedical factors in the explanation of relative socio-economic inequalities in mortality: evidence from the HUNT study
Int J Epidemiol
,
2009
, vol.
38
(pg.
1272
-
84
)
29
Akselsen
A
Dahl
G
Lajord
J
Sivertstol
O
,
FD-trygd. Variabelliste [Database on social security—list of variables] Notater 2000/70
,
2000
Oslo/Kongsvinger
Statistics Norway
30
Rahkonen
O
Arber
S
Lahelma
E
et al.
,
Understanding income inequalities in health among men and women in Britain and Finland
Int J Health Serv
,
2000
, vol.
30
(pg.
27
-
47
)
31
Martikainen
P
Mäkelä
P
Koskinen
S
Valkonen
T
,
Income differences in mortality: a register-based follow-up study of three million men and women
Int J Epidemiol
,
2001
, vol.
30
(pg.
1397
-
405
)
32
Kunst
A
Bos
V
Mackenbach
J
The EU working group on socioeconomic inequalities in health
.
,
Monitoring socioeconomic inequalities in the European Union: guidelines and illustrations
,
2001
Rotterdam
Erasmus University, Department of Public Health

Supplementary data

Comments

0 Comments
Submit a comment
You have entered an invalid code
Thank you for submitting a comment on this article. Your comment will be reviewed and published at the journal's discretion. Please check for further notifications by email.