Abstract

New estimates on the premodern economic growth of Japan, based on more concrete evidence, have been presented. We revise the estimates of Japan’s gross domestic product (GDP) from the mid-eighth century to the mid-19th century and its population in the 12th century and describe the institutional transformations that correspond to the output changes. The revision of output and population results in updated estimates of per capita GDP for the medieval period and extension of the growth estimates in the early modern period to the annual series for 1651–1841. This study employs the techniques of quantitative inference and descriptive interpretation of the estimated performance. The findings show that: (a) Both the GDP and population significantly declined towards the 12th century, stagnated and experienced recovery from the 13th century onwards, and then continued to grow through the 17th century; (b) GDP growth accelerated in the 18th and 19th centuries; and (c) per capita GDP growth began to rise in the 13th century after a sharp decline from the 10th to 12th centuries. It continued to rise through the 16th century but declined again in the mid-17th century and finally rose again from the late 17th century onwards.

1. Introduction

Major advanced economies, including Japan, began to experience accelerated productivity growth in the early modern period, that is, around the 17th and 18th centuries, before being fully modernised in the 19th century. Globally, the East and West diverged in that period. Regionally, northwestern Europe advanced within Europe, and Japan advanced within East Asia at that time. An inquiry into early modern changes is thus critical to understanding how major advanced economies emerged. Furthermore, to understand the early modern ascendance of these economies, we need to pay attention to their stagnant or much more modest growth in the medieval period. Acceleration of the productivity growth over the centuries has also accompanied institutional transformations. The direction of causality, however, is hard to pin down. Institutions might affect technological changes and economic developments, as Hegel (1986) and North (2005) argued. Alternatively, as Marx (1986) discussed, economic developments might bring about institutional changes. To disentangle the complexity, we may construct a time series of gross domestic product (GDP) per person, an indicator of productivity, for each country from the ancient and medieval periods to today and match institutional changes with economic performance throughout the past to comprehend how our current economy has been formed, and possibly, to identify the causality between changes in institutions and economic performance. The late Angus Maddison’s project on the per capita GDP of nations was one such attempt.1 Although per-country performance evidence was not particularly strong in Maddison’s project, it certainly represented a breakthrough as a political economy approach. Maddison suggested that current economic performance can be forecast by past performance over a few centuries and hence, in all probability, by the past changes in institutions in the past few centuries. Updating the estimates was a task left to subsequent scholars.

Regarding Japan’s past, studies by Fukao et al. (2017b), Fukao et al. (2017a), Takashima (2017), and Bassino et al. (2019) are some of the recent works estimating Japan’s GDP from the 730s to the 1870s, effectively replacing the estimate by Angus Maddison. Unlike Maddison’s work, the new estimates depend more on historical documents of the supply side, except for the period between the 13th century and the 15th century for which they estimate output by estimates of demand. These publications are part of a project by the Institute of Economic Research at Hitotsubashi University.2

First, we revise the output estimate for the medieval period presented by Fukao et al. (2017a), Takashima (2017), and Bassino et al. (2019). In these works, the authors estimate the agricultural output using historical documents on paddy fields with respect to the supply side for the seventh to 12th as well as the 16th centuries and onwards. The output for the 13th to 15th centuries was calculated using an estimate of demand based on the real wage estimates by the authors and the population estimate by Farris (2006, 2009).

In a later study, Midorikawa (2019) estimates the rice output from the mid-eighth century through the late 16th century only using historical documents of paddy fields such as taxation records and ancient encyclopaedias. Thus, the author provides estimates based on supply-side data through the ancient and medieval periods. Further, the author accounts for climate cooling from the 10th to 12th centuries and considerably revises the previous estimates downwards. Adjusting the estimate by Midorikawa (2019), we construct a consistent estimate of agricultural output from the eighth century to the late 16th century based entirely on supply-side data.

The Midorikawa (2019) estimate also helps us revise the population estimate by Farris (2009). In Farris (2006, 2009), the population is estimated based on historical documents on the surface of farmland as well as the author’s assumptions of land productivity and living standards. Thus, the downward revision of land productivity for the 12th century by Midorikawa (2019) motivates us to revise the population estimate by Farris (2009) simultaneously.

Second, we extend the output estimate for the early modern period by Fukao et al. (2017b) and Bassino et al. (2019). Fukao et al. (2017b) present the output estimates for several years from the 17th century to the 19th century. Imamura and Nakabayashi (2017) further revise the estimate by Nakabayashi (2012) of the annual agricultural output of the Edo (Tokugawa) shogunate (1600[1603]–1867) domain for the mid-17th century through the mid-19th century. Combining the estimated national output by Fukao et al. (2017b) and the shogunate’s annual agricultural output by Imamura and Nakabayashi (2017), with adjustment for possible oversight in cadastral surveys, we construct the national annual output estimates for the mid-17th century through the mid-19th century.

Third, we summarise the performance of the annual national output in the form of per capita GDP from the medieval to early modern periods. With our updated estimates of the GDP and population for this period, our new estimate shows a sharp decline towards the 12th century and recovery from the 13th to 16th centuries, whereas the previous estimates of the GDP per person show extended stagnancy between the ninth and 14th centuries. For the early modern period from the 17th century onwards, we provide an annual estimate from 1651 to 1841.

Fourth, we empirically show that the agricultural output in the early modern period was responsive to prices, indicating that farmers were exposed to the market.

Fifth, surveying qualitative arguments based on descriptive works, we review the institutional changes behind the intensive and extensive margins of growth from the ancient to modern periods estimated herein. We observe a considerable change in the productivity in the early modern period, as peasants’ smallholdings were protected as property rights. By property rights, we mean two connected rights: residual control rights, which allowed landholders to use their land as they determined, but within the constraints of the law, contracts, and customs; and residual claims, which were the leftovers after the holder performed all financial obligations under the law, contracts, and customs (Hart 1988). If farmers were exposed to the market, the protection of their property rights would provide them with incentives for productivity improvements. Our quantitative results on productivity and the output’s responsiveness to prices are consistent with the emphasis on the protection of smallholders’ property rights by qualitative arguments.

Our contribution to the literature is two-fold. First, our revision and extension of the output estimates by Fukao et al. (2017a), Fukao et al. (2017b), Takashima (2017), and Bassino et al. (2019) as well as our revision of population estimates by Farris (2009) provide a more reliable and detailed estimate of the output and population of Japan through the mid-19th century. Notably, we find that the productivity recovery in the medieval period began in the 13th century and that the early modern acceleration of productivity growth began in the late 17th century. Second, our results offer a rigorous viewpoint for two debates on the ‘little divergence in Asia’ and the ‘state capacity’ of pre-industrial societies.

As Bassino et al. (2019) demonstrate, and as we review in section 4, Japan’s per capita GDP surpassed China’s for the first time in its history in the 18th century, and Japan has continued to widen the lead since then. Its per capita GDP came close to those of peripheral European countries by the early-19th century. This development resembles the divergence between northern and southern Europe and is considered the ‘little divergence in Asia’ (Bassino et al. 2019). Meanwhile, from the early-19th century onwards, notably after the Napoleonic war, European nations accelerated their productivity growth by opening their markets, enabling free international trade, and allowing cross-border technology transfer. Thus, the shogunate’s isolationist policy exacerbated Japan’s relative backwardness with respect to the West (Schreurs 2019; Broadberry and Fukao (Forthcoming)).

As presented in sections 2, 3, and 4, and discussed in section 5, the rise in productivity began in the period of the Kamakura shogunate. It accelerated in the 15th to 16th centuries, when the manorial (shoen, estate) system collapsed and local feudal lords gained power. Later, productivity accelerated further from the late 17th century onwards under the Edo shogunate. Under the manorial system, the largest recipients of the land tax revenue were manorial lords in imperial Kyoto. Thus, the transition of power accompanied a decentralisation of the land tax revenue. This fiscal decentralisation financed the nation-wide reclamation of alluvial plains in the lower reaches and city buildings in the 17th century under the Edo shogunate federation. Further, the shogunate and local lords in developed domains vested farmers with property rights in the 17th century. The protection of property rights provided smallholders with incentives to improve productivity.

Our new output estimates are relevant to the debate on ‘state capacity’. State capacity denotes the ability to levy a tax in order to provide public goods, and it is measured by the tax rate over the output. We know that British ascendance in the West and Japanese ascendance in the East were accompanied by higher state capacities (Dincecco (2009, 2011); Dincecco and Prado (2012); Dincecco and Katz (2014); Sng and Moriguchi (2014); Aoki, Che and Nakabayashi (2016); Dincecco and Onorato (2016); Koyama, Moriguchi and Sng (2018); Cox and Dincecco (Forthcoming)). In the 17th century, when the shogunate established farmers’ property rights, the tax rate reached 30% of the GDP in return for property rights protections. Though the rate declined over time as productivity grew, it remained at 14% in the mid-19th century. This rate was comparable to the English rate in the late 1810s after the Napoleonic Wars (O’Brien and Hunt 1993: 175), and higher than Spain’s 10% rate in the 17th century (Comín Comín and Yun-Casalilla 2012: 244), China’s 8% rate in the mid-19th century (Deng 2012: 342), and Turkey’s less than 8% rate in the mid-19th century (Pamuk 2012: 321). Institutional arrangements to protect farmers’ property rights under the Edo shogunate not only provided farmers with incentives to improve productivity but also bequeathed substantial state capacity to Meiji Japan for modernisation.

We organise the rest of the article as follows. In section 2, we revise the Fukao et al. (2017a) estimate of Japan’s GDP in the medieval period by incorporating a new estimate by Midorikawa (2019). Based on Midorikawa (2019), we also revise the Farris (2009) population estimate for the 12th century. In section 3, we extend the Fukao et al. (2017b) GDP estimate in the early modern period by combining it with the estimate by Imamura and Nakabayashi (2017). Section 4 summarises our estimates of the output and population in the form of the GDP per person from the eighth to 19th centuries. We then empirically test whether the agricultural output responded to prices in the early modern period. The output’s price responsiveness indicates whether farmers were exposed to the market—if not, then they would not have significantly responded to the prices, and the incentive effects of smallholders’ property rights protection in the early modern period would have been quite limited. Thus, the empirical test is critical to the qualitative evaluation. Next, section 5 reviews the institutional changes consistent with the evolution of economic performance. Finally, section 6 concludes the article with a summary of the estimate results as well as a discussion of the implications of historical legacy from the examined period.

2. Estimates for the Medieval Period

2.1. Agricultural Output

The GDP estimates of Fukao et al. (2017a) and Bassino et al. (2019) are based on the estimates of agricultural products by Takashima (2017). For the years 730, 950, and 1150, Takashima (2017) estimates the agricultural output from existing documents by the imperial court and ancient encyclopaedias. For the year 1600, Takashima (2017) uses documents left by feudal lords.

For the years 1280 and 1450, Takashima (2017) estimates the demand for food by his estimates of real wages and the population estimates by Farris (2006, 2009). Takashima (2017), Fukao et al. (2017a), and Bassino et al. (2019) accordingly extrapolate the agricultural output. This demand-side approach will be refined in the same way as the real wage estimates are updated (Saito and Takashima 2020).

For the years 730, 950, 1150, 1280, and 1450, Takashima (2017) presents ranges of estimates. The output estimates by Fukao et al. (2017a) and Bassino et al. (2019) adopt a median of ranges estimated by Takashima (2017).

Meanwhile, Midorikawa (2019) estimates rice crops from the early eighth to the late 15th century using ancient encyclopaedias and documents such as the taxation records left by the imperial court. Thus, for the entire ancient and medieval periods, Midorikawa (2019) adopts the approach taken by Takashima (2017) for the period between 730 and 1150. Figure 1 compares these estimates.

Comparison of Takashima and Midorikawa’s Estimates. Source: Takashima (2017: 101) and Midorikawa (2019: 22).
Figure 1.

Comparison of Takashima and Midorikawa’s Estimates. Source: Takashima (2017: 101) and Midorikawa (2019: 22).

First, we find that, except for the year 1150, the median estimates of the total agricultural output by Takashima (2017) are comparable with the estimates of the rice output by Midorikawa (2019), including the years for which Takashima (2017) estimates the agricultural output by the demand-side approach based on real wages and population estimates.

The unit of output used by Midorikawa (2019) is the taxation unit that Midorikawa (2016) examines. There were two alternative hypotheses for the taxation unit used from the eighth to 10th centuries: Midorikawa (2016) persuasively infers that farmers could not have survived on parcels of farmland allocated by the rules of the Taiho Imperial Legal Code (Taiho Ritsu Ryo) of 701 if the pessimistic hypothesis had been correct. The author concludes that the unit supported by the optimistic hypothesis was thus applied.

The rice-denominated unit for taxation did not necessarily correspond to rice plants. In general, agricultural output was denominated by rice and then taxed. An example is the payment of land taxes and rents in cash. The Japanese economy was rapidly monetised after the 12th century as part of the Chinese currency sphere (Sakurai 2008; Segal 2011: 45–65; Honda 2017). The mountainous regions were among the first to accept money in the earliest phase, as rice there could not be cultivated and land-tax payments in cash were preferred (Oyama 1979). We infer that the ‘rice’ output estimated by Midorikawa (2016) covers the entire agricultural output.

Second, for the years 1280 and 1450, the estimates by Takashima (2017) and Midorikawa (2019) are mutually complementary. While the estimate by Takashima (2017) uses the demand-side evidence, Midorikawa (2019) relies on supply-side evidence. Nevertheless, both reach similar estimates, indicating the degree of accuracy of both approaches.

Third, the median of the estimate by Takashima (2017) substantially differs from that by Midorikawa (2019) for the year 1150. For this year, both Takashima (2017) and Midorikawa (2019) adopt the source that indicates the surface of farmland. The difference primarily depends on the assumption of land productivity, which was affected by the intensity of farming. Notably, consecutive famines struck Japan from the 12th to mid-13th centuries: the Tenei Famine in 1110; the Genei Famine in 1118–1119; the Daiji Famine in 1127–1128; the Chōshō and Hōen Famine in 1133–1135; the Kyūan, Ninpei, and Kyūju Famine in 1150–1156; the Ōhō Famine in 1161; the Yōwa Famine in 1181; the Jōan and Angen Famine in 1174–1175; the Kanki Famine in 1230–1231; and the Shōka Famine in 1258–1259 (Isogai 2008). In this regard, the downwards trend portrayed by Midorikawa (2019) seems conceivable. From the trend of the adjacent estimate years, we adopt the low estimate of Takashima (2017) for 1150.

2.2. Division of Labour and Urbanisation

Manorial lords in Kyoto and Nara in the medieval period ruled manors all over Japan. They collected half of the agricultural output in the 11th and 12th centuries. Although the rate declined with improvements in productivity, the distribution of agricultural produce to manorial lords still amounted to one-third of total output in the 14th and 15th centuries (Nishitani and Nakabayashi 2017). This income distribution, which was enormously skewed towards manorial lords who lived in Kyoto and Nara, created a substantial demand for consumer goods (Wakita 1975).

Therefore, in the early stage of the manorial system from the ninth to 11th centuries, manorial lords strengthened the division of labour within and among manors by protecting merchants and artisans. Manorial lords vested the privilege of regional monopoly in guilds of merchants and artisans. These guilds contributed to the expansion of the secondary and tertiary sectors. The division of labour and trade of commodities within and among manors expanded trading among local merchants, artisans, and consumers, particularly from the 12th century onwards when copper coins imported from China began to circulate as currency. Local markets, especially the Kyoto market, emerged from the division of labour under the manorial system (Suzuki 2017; Watanuki 2017; Sakurai 2018).

For the population, the census presided over by the shogunate has been available since 1721. For periods before the shogunate census began, Farris (2006, 2009) estimates the population from the eighth to 15th centuries and Saito (2018) from 1600 onwards. In the method by Farris (2009), the acreage of farmland is divided by the productivity assumed to be necessary to sustain a person, which is expressed as tan (= 0.1 cho = 0.140 ha). Farris (2009) assumes that it was 2.17 tan for 950 and 1.975 for 1150 (Farris 2009: 24–27).

However, Midorikawa (2019) demonstrates that the land productivity of wet-rice farming fell drastically from the 10th to the 11th centuries because of climate cooling. Midorikawa (2019) estimates the land productivities for the years 876, 914, 1023, 1115, 1166, and 1206. From the estimates, the average of years 876, 914, and 1023 is obtained as 1.01 koku per tan and that of 1115, 1166, and 1206 is 0.78koku per tan (Supplementary Appendix A.I.2). Thus, land productivity around the mid-12th century fell to 77.23% (=0.78/1.01) of its value from the mid-10th century. Therefore, accepting 2.17 as the divider of the acreage for the year 950, we obtain 2.8102.17/0.7723, instead of 1.975 for the year 1150 as provided by Farris (2009: 24–27).

Regarding the acreage of paddy fields, the numbers adopted by Farris (2009) and the estimates by Midorikawa (2019) do not show a substantial discrepancy. Farris (2009) assumes that it was 717,419 cho for the year 1150 (Farris 2009: 22), while Midorikawa (2019) estimates the acreage of paddy fields to be 717,000 cho for the years 735, 804, and 876; 721,000 cho for 914; 725,000 cho for 1023; and 734,000 cho for 1115 (Supplementary Appendix A.I.2). Thus, dividing 7,340,000 tan by 2.810, we obtain 2,612,100. To include the population in non-farm sectors, we multiply the number by 1.4 and add the urban population, 200,000, following Farris (2009). We then obtain a population of 3,856,940. Rounding up the number, we estimate the population range in 1150 as 3.7–4.1 million. Our revised population estimates are presented in Table 1.

Meanwhile, Saito and Takashima (2017a) investigate cities and towns recorded in existing historical documents and estimate an urban population with more than 1,000 residents. As figures 2, 3, and 4 show, cities and towns emerged around the junctions of trade centres such as ports.

Medieval Cities, 1300. Source: Saito and Takashima (2017a: 72).
Figure 2.

Medieval Cities, 1300. Source: Saito and Takashima (2017a: 72).

Medieval Cities, 1300–1500. Source: Saito and Takashima (2017a: 72).
Figure 3.

Medieval Cities, 1300–1500. Source: Saito and Takashima (2017a: 72).

Medieval Cities, 1500–1600. Source: Saito and Takashima (2017a: 72).
Figure 4.

Medieval Cities, 1500–1600. Source: Saito and Takashima (2017a: 72).

Among the cities and towns they identified, Saito and Takashima (2017a) and Fukao et al. (2017a) counted cities with an estimated population of 10,000 or more, defining population in such cities as urban population, and compared the number with population estimates by Farris (2006, 2009), as in Table 1.

Table 1.

Population and Urban Population, 730–1874

YearPopulationUrban Population (Thousands)Urbanization Rate (%)
High Estimate (Thousands)Low Estimate (Thousands)Mean (Thousands)
7306,4005,8006,1001242.0
9505,6004,4005,0001352.7
11504,1003,7003,9001203.1
12806,2005,7005,9502083.5
145010,5009,60010,0502592.6
160017,0001,0886.4
172131,2903,96012.7
180430,6903,94012.8
184632,2103,96012.3
187434,8403,58810.3
YearPopulationUrban Population (Thousands)Urbanization Rate (%)
High Estimate (Thousands)Low Estimate (Thousands)Mean (Thousands)
7306,4005,8006,1001242.0
9505,6004,4005,0001352.7
11504,1003,7003,9001203.1
12806,2005,7005,9502083.5
145010,5009,60010,0502592.6
160017,0001,0886.4
172131,2903,96012.7
180430,6903,94012.8
184632,2103,96012.3
187434,8403,58810.3

Source: The total population for the year 1150: This study (see the text). For others, see Saito and Takashima (2017a: 76); Fukao et al. (2017a: 290); and Fukao et al. (2017b: 285). Farris (2006, 2009) provide the original sources for the years 730–1450 and Saito (2018) for 1600.

Table 1.

Population and Urban Population, 730–1874

YearPopulationUrban Population (Thousands)Urbanization Rate (%)
High Estimate (Thousands)Low Estimate (Thousands)Mean (Thousands)
7306,4005,8006,1001242.0
9505,6004,4005,0001352.7
11504,1003,7003,9001203.1
12806,2005,7005,9502083.5
145010,5009,60010,0502592.6
160017,0001,0886.4
172131,2903,96012.7
180430,6903,94012.8
184632,2103,96012.3
187434,8403,58810.3
YearPopulationUrban Population (Thousands)Urbanization Rate (%)
High Estimate (Thousands)Low Estimate (Thousands)Mean (Thousands)
7306,4005,8006,1001242.0
9505,6004,4005,0001352.7
11504,1003,7003,9001203.1
12806,2005,7005,9502083.5
145010,5009,60010,0502592.6
160017,0001,0886.4
172131,2903,96012.7
180430,6903,94012.8
184632,2103,96012.3
187434,8403,58810.3

Source: The total population for the year 1150: This study (see the text). For others, see Saito and Takashima (2017a: 76); Fukao et al. (2017a: 290); and Fukao et al. (2017b: 285). Farris (2006, 2009) provide the original sources for the years 730–1450 and Saito (2018) for 1600.

Smith (1937[1776]) argues that the depth of the division of labour tends to increase with the size of the market (Smith 1937[1776]: 17–21), which, in turn, can be approximated by population density and urbanisation (Malanima 2005, 2010). Saito and Takashima (2016) estimate the weights of the secondary and tertiary sectors for 1600, 1721, and 1846 by projecting the relationship between the secondary and tertiary sectors, population density, and the urbanisation rate in 1874.

Fukao et al. (2017a), Fukao et al. (2017b), and Bassino et al. (2019) apply the same relationships between the output of the non-farm sector, population density, and urbanisation rate to the ancient and medieval periods, and thus estimate the sectoral output composition of the GDP from the eighth century, as shown in Table 2. The estimates might not be perfectly precise, but we believe that the estimation of the non-farm sector using population data is straightforward and tractable.

Table 2.

Sectoral Composition, 730–1874

YearPrimary (%)Secondary (%)Tertiary (%)
7308668
9508758
11508768
12808569
145082711
160074918
1721631126
1804631126
1846631126
1874601228
YearPrimary (%)Secondary (%)Tertiary (%)
7308668
9508758
11508768
12808569
145082711
160074918
1721631126
1804631126
1846631126
1874601228
Table 2.

Sectoral Composition, 730–1874

YearPrimary (%)Secondary (%)Tertiary (%)
7308668
9508758
11508768
12808569
145082711
160074918
1721631126
1804631126
1846631126
1874601228
YearPrimary (%)Secondary (%)Tertiary (%)
7308668
9508758
11508768
12808569
145082711
160074918
1721631126
1804631126
1846631126
1874601228

2.3. Gross Domestic Product

As discussed, referencing Midorikawa (2019), we adopt the low estimate of agricultural output by Takashima (2017) for 1150 and the median estimates for the other years. As estimated by Fukao et al. (2017a), we assume here that the agricultural output amounted to 84.36% of subtotal of the primary sector. Using the sectoral composition shown in Table 2, we obtain the GDP estimates, as shown in Table 3.

Table 3.

Gross Domestic Product, 730–1600

YearPrimarySecondaryTertiaryTotal
AgriculturePrimary Subtotal
kokukokukokukokukokuThousands of 1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollars
7306,3297,5024787138,6932,367
9507,9909,47157988510,9242,975
11505,2996,2813995887,2621,977
12808,2989,8366731,09011,6003,159
145014,01616,6151,3742,22320,2125,504
160025,87930,6773,6637,28441,62411,334
YearPrimarySecondaryTertiaryTotal
AgriculturePrimary Subtotal
kokukokukokukokukokuThousands of 1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollars
7306,3297,5024787138,6932,367
9507,9909,47157988510,9242,975
11505,2996,2813995887,2621,977
12808,2989,8366731,09011,6003,159
145014,01616,6151,3742,22320,2125,504
160025,87930,6773,6637,28441,62411,334

Source: 1150: This study (see the text). Other years: Takashima (2017: 101) and Fukao et al. (2017a: 202–293).

Table 3.

Gross Domestic Product, 730–1600

YearPrimarySecondaryTertiaryTotal
AgriculturePrimary Subtotal
kokukokukokukokukokuThousands of 1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollars
7306,3297,5024787138,6932,367
9507,9909,47157988510,9242,975
11505,2996,2813995887,2621,977
12808,2989,8366731,09011,6003,159
145014,01616,6151,3742,22320,2125,504
160025,87930,6773,6637,28441,62411,334
YearPrimarySecondaryTertiaryTotal
AgriculturePrimary Subtotal
kokukokukokukokukokuThousands of 1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollars
7306,3297,5024787138,6932,367
9507,9909,47157988510,9242,975
11505,2996,2813995887,2621,977
12808,2989,8366731,09011,6003,159
145014,01616,6151,3742,22320,2125,504
160025,87930,6773,6637,28441,62411,334

Source: 1150: This study (see the text). Other years: Takashima (2017: 101) and Fukao et al. (2017a: 202–293).

By connecting the agricultural output estimates by Takashima (2017) and Midorikawa (2019), we add estimate points for GDP to those by Fukao et al. (2017a) (Supplementary Appendix A.I.1). Figure 5 shows the estimates of the GDP from 730 to 1600 in terms of the 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollar.

Gross Domestic Product, 730–1600. Source:Supplementary Appendix A.I.1. Takashima (2017: 101) and Fukao et al. (2017a) provide the original sources for the years 730, 950, 1150, 1450, and 1600. For the other years, the source is Midorikawa (2019). Notes: For 1150, we adopted the low estimate of agricultural output by Takashima (2017: 101). We convert the output in terms of koku by applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars.
Figure 5.

Gross Domestic Product, 730–1600. Source:Supplementary Appendix A.I.1. Takashima (2017: 101) and Fukao et al. (2017a) provide the original sources for the years 730, 950, 1150, 1450, and 1600. For the other years, the source is Midorikawa (2019). Notes: For 1150, we adopted the low estimate of agricultural output by Takashima (2017: 101). We convert the output in terms of koku by applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars.

3. Estimates for the Early Modern Period

3.1. Output of the Shogunate Domain

The Edo shogunate governed all of Japan as the central government from 1600 to 1868. Tokugawa Japan was a federation in which the shogunate and lords were fiscally independent, and the shogunate solely relied on the tax revenue from its domain (Ravina 1999: 16–45). Regarding the shogunate domain, the output and predicted land taxes transcribed by shogunate officials for 1651 to 1841 are available.3

Land tax was based on cadastral surveys conducted by samurai officials. In cadastral surveys the shogunate specified each parcel of farmland, identified the stem family who cultivated the parcel, estimated the average output from the parcel, and decided the officially predicted output and land tax for the parcel. In the shogunate domain, the cadastral survey was completed in the 1670s to match every parcel of farmland with a specific farming household.If a family paid the land tax decided by the cadastral surveys, the shogunate court protected the property rights of the family against bystanders (Nakabayashi 2020).

While the land tax was payable either in cash or in kind by rice, the unit of representation of the output and land tax was that of rice, koku, where 1 koku equals 180.38 litres. While rice was widely grown in early modern Japan, other kinds of crops were also grown. All agricultural output was converted to the equivalent amount of rice, recorded in koku, and taxed. In Supplementary Appendix A.II, series a shows the recorded output, series b shows the land tax revenue, and series c shows the amount collected in rice out of the total land-tax revenue.

Thus, by tracking the tax basis recorded in koku, as seen in series a in Supplementary Appendix A.II, we know the officially predicted output of each region. However, raw output data (koku daka) tended to undervalue the actual output. As we discuss in section 5, the stability of the owner-peasant economy was essential to the shogunate. Meanwhile, the shogunate and lords pretended that they imposed a high tax rate. One solution was an allowance given when farmland was surveyed. When each parcel was surveyed, on average, 15% of the measured area was subtracted from the tax basis to provide a safety margin to stabilise owner peasants.4

Therefore, even if we can assume that the shogunate could survey all the agricultural output, the actual output on average would be 1.176(1/0.85) times the recorded output, as shown in series d (=a/0.85) in Supplementary Appendix A.II.

In the Kyōhō era (1716–1736) under the reign of Shogun Yoshimune Tokugawa, the shogunate conducted a reform of land taxes. Before the reform, fixed-rate taxation had been implemented. The collected land tax amount was, technically, a fixed percentage of the inspected crop each year. The taxation policy was changed to a fixed amount in the Kyōhō era.

The last cadastral survey in the shogunate domain was conducted in the 1690s. Thereafter, no substantial cadastral survey was conducted until the shogunate’s collapse in 1868. Effectively, the shogunate ceased trying to measure productivity growth after the Kyōhō era reform.

Thus, we assume that the shogunate tracked productivity growth up to 1715 and failed to do so from 1716 onwards. Given the assumption, we estimate the primary sector output based on the shogunate’s official record of output until 1715. Beyond 1715, the shogunate ceased to track growth in the agricultural output, and its record is considered to have been an underestimate of the actual output. Therefore, for years beyond 1715, we estimate the long-term trend of growth in the primary sector by the benchmark estimate years of 1600, 1721, 1804, and 1846 in Fukao et al. (2017b) and linear interpolation between the years. We then multiply the shogunate’s recorded agricultural output by the estimated trend to obtain the actual agricultural output of the shogunate domain from 1716 onwards.

For productivity, Fukao et al. (2017b) present the estimates of the primary-sector output per person at the national level for the years 1600, 1721, 1804, and 1846. We construct annual series trends using linear interpolation between two-point estimates, as shown in series j in Supplementary Appendix A.II.

We conservatively assume that the shogunate gathered data on 90% of the actual output until 1715, as shown in series e(=d/0.9) in Supplementary Appendix A.II. We also assume that the shogunate ceased to track productivity growth after 1716; hence, series a does not reflect changes in the agricultural output per person from 1716. Thus, we estimate the actual agricultural output in year t as gt = et × jt/j1716 from 1716, as shown in series g in Supplementary Appendix A.II. Series e is inserted into g for the period from 1651 to 1715. As Fukao et al. (2017a), Fukao et al. (2017b), and Takashima (2017), we assume that the agricultural output amounted to 84.36% of the subtotal of the primary-sector output in order to obtain the output of the primary sector, i =g/0.8346.

Fukao et al. (2017b) estimate sector composition at the national level for 1600, 1721, 1804, and 1846 (Table 2). We construct the annual series of the ratio of the primary sector based on the linear trends between two estimate years, as shown in series k in Supplementary Appendix A.II. Then, we show the gross domestic output of the shogunate domain as series l = i/k in Supplementary Appendix A.II. By converting the l series in koku by 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars, following Fukao et al. (2017b), we obtain the GDP of the shogunate domain in 1990 Geary–Khamis international dollars, as shown in series m in Supplementary Appendix A.II. Figure 6 draws the estimated output, recorded output, and land tax revenue.

Output and Land Tax of the Shogunate Domain, 1651–1841. Source: Supplementary Appendix A.II. Original sources: Ono (1996: 441–448) (for 1651–1715, ‘Okouchi ke kiroku’ (Records of the Okouchi family), Ono, ed (2008b: 106–130); and for 1716–1841, ‘Mukoyama Seisai zakki oyobi zattetsu’ (Memoranda and notes by Seisai Mukoyama), Ono, ed (2008a: 62–80); Fukao et al. (2017b); and Oishi (1969[1794]: 73)).
Figure 6.

Output and Land Tax of the Shogunate Domain, 1651–1841. Source: Supplementary Appendix A.II. Original sources: Ono (1996: 441–448) (for 1651–1715, ‘Okouchi ke kiroku’ (Records of the Okouchi family), Ono, ed (2008b: 106–130); and for 1716–1841, ‘Mukoyama Seisai zakki oyobi zattetsu’ (Memoranda and notes by Seisai Mukoyama), Ono, ed (2008a: 62–80); Fukao et al. (2017b); and Oishi (1969[1794]: 73)).

The volatility in the 17th century reflects the effects of famines. As a response, the shogunate and lords mandated savings as community damage insurance. Note that, as we discuss in section 5, the shogunate prevented the financial industry in cities from penetrating rural villages. Damage insurance was to take the form of microfinance in village communities. One early case was adopted by Lord Masayuki Hoshina in the mid-17th century, who governed the Aizu domain (Western part of the Fukushima prefecture). Lord Hoshina not only reduced land tax in periods of poor harvests but also obliged farmers to save rice to insure themselves against famines. The shogunate under the Kansei reform led by Minister Sadanobu Matsudaira in the late 18th century mandated farmers and city residents to save against possible famines (Makihara 2017).

Such insurance also mattered for output in the following years. The shortage of food alone did not directly result in mass deaths. Famine, dysfunctional governance, lack of quarantine measures, poor savings to smooth consumption, and food shortages from poor harvests were followed by a pandemic and severe damage to output (Saito 2002, 2015a; Saito and Takashima 2017a).

3.2. National Output

Relying on cadastral survey documents by the shogunate and lords, Fukao et al. (2017b) estimate primary sector output; applying the approach of Saito and Takashima (2016), we estimate the output of the secondary and tertiary sectors, as shown in Table 4. In the early modern period, the division of labour and growth in the secondary and tertiary sectors were substantially driven by the growing allocation of seasonally slack labour within farming households. Under the shogunate’s isolationist policy, the growing population was inevitably matched by growth in agriculture, the driving force of productivity growth. Demand in the secondary and tertiary sectors caused by urbanisation was met by side jobs taken up by farmers and young temporary workers who migrated temporarily from rural villages. Moreover, local towns surrounded by rural villages grew as industrial, commercial clusters in the 18th and 19th centuries. While skilled artisans gathered in such towns, they did not necessarily cut their ties with families in their home villages (Saito 1983, 2009; Saito and Takashima 2017b; Mandai 2019: 279–480). Therefore, the sectoral composition of the secondary and tertiary sectors was stably proportional to the primary sector throughout the early modern period.

Table 4.

Gross Domestic Product, 1600–1874

YearPrimary (Million koku)Secondary (Million koku)Tertiary (Million koku)Total (Million koku)Millions of 1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollars
160030.7003.6007.30041.60011,328
172148.8108.43020.36077.60021,131
180458.80010.09024.40093.30025,407
184667.06011.70028.140106.90029,110
187477.10315.88836.551129.54135,275
YearPrimary (Million koku)Secondary (Million koku)Tertiary (Million koku)Total (Million koku)Millions of 1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollars
160030.7003.6007.30041.60011,328
172148.8108.43020.36077.60021,131
180458.80010.09024.40093.30025,407
184667.06011.70028.140106.90029,110
187477.10315.88836.551129.54135,275

Notes: We converted koku to 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars bsy applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars. Then we obtained the composition ratio of the output from the shogunate domain over the national output for the years 1600, 1721, 1804, and 1846.

Table 4.

Gross Domestic Product, 1600–1874

YearPrimary (Million koku)Secondary (Million koku)Tertiary (Million koku)Total (Million koku)Millions of 1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollars
160030.7003.6007.30041.60011,328
172148.8108.43020.36077.60021,131
180458.80010.09024.40093.30025,407
184667.06011.70028.140106.90029,110
187477.10315.88836.551129.54135,275
YearPrimary (Million koku)Secondary (Million koku)Tertiary (Million koku)Total (Million koku)Millions of 1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollars
160030.7003.6007.30041.60011,328
172148.8108.43020.36077.60021,131
180458.80010.09024.40093.30025,407
184667.06011.70028.140106.90029,110
187477.10315.88836.551129.54135,275

Notes: We converted koku to 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars bsy applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars. Then we obtained the composition ratio of the output from the shogunate domain over the national output for the years 1600, 1721, 1804, and 1846.

Here, we apply the ratio of the output of the shogunate over the national output in 1721 to the period from 1651 to 1715. For 1722 to 1803, we fill in the linear trend of the ratio between 1721 and 1804, when point estimates by Fukao et al. (2017b) are available. For 1805 to 1851, we use the relative output of the shogunate in 1851 over the national output in 1846 to calculate national output in 1851 and thus fill in the linear trend of the ratio between 1804 and 1851. The constructed annual ratio is shown as series q in Supplementary Appendix A.II. Then, we obtain the annual series of the GDP of the national level by dividing the output from the shogunate domain l by q such that r(=l/q) in Supplementary Appendix A.II.

We also fill in the linear trend of the population between estimate years, 1600, 1721, 1804, 1846, and 1874 (Table 1), displayed as series t in Supplementary Appendix A.II. Then, we obtain the per capita GDP as series u =r/t in Supplementary Appendix A.II. Figure 7 draws a series of the GDP r and per capita GDP u. Our estimate results for benchmark years are presented in Table 5, whereas Figure 7 displays all years.

Table 5.

Our Estimate of Gross Domestic Product in Early Modern Times, 1651‒1841

YearOutput and tax revenue of the shogunate domain
Officially estimated outputLand tax revenueOfficially estimated output adjusted for allowanceOutput adjusted for oversightEffective tax rate of the agricultural sector, estimated by the shogunateEstimated agricultural outputEffective tax rate of the agricultural sectorSubtotal of the primary sectorNational output of the primary sector per personSectoral composition of the primary sector: (National primary sector output)/(Gross domestic product of the national level)
Thousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand koku
abd(=a/0.85)e(= d/0.9)f(=1.25b/d)gh(=1.25b/g)i(=g/0.8436)jk
16001.80 0.737
16572,925 1,120 3,442 3,824 41%3,824 37%4,533 1.69 0.686
16622,734 1,100 3,217 3,574 43%3,574 38%4,237 1.68 0.682
16712,975 1,131 3,500 3,889 40%3,889 36%4,609 1.66 0.674
16813,401 1,026 4,001 4,446 32%4,446 29%5,270 1.64 0.665
16913,971 1,354 4,672 5,191 36%5,191 33%6,154 1.62 0.656
17013,849 1,115 4,529 5,032 31%5,032 28%5,965 1.60 0.647
17114,144 1,300 4,876 5,417 33%5,417 30%6,422 1.59 0.638
17214,067 1,306 4,784 5,316 34%5,283 31%6,263 1.57 0.629
17314,531 1,365 5,330 5,923 32%6,026 28%7,143 1.60 0.629
17414,586 1,570 5,396 5,995 36%6,265 31%7,426 1.65 0.629
17514,395 1,705 5,170 5,744 41%6,161 35%7,303 1.69 0.629
17614,466 1,680 5,254 5,837 40%6,421 33%7,612 1.73 0.629
17714,376 1,353 5,148 5,720 33%6,449 26%7,645 1.78 0.630
17814,348 1,466 5,116 5,684 36%6,565 28%7,782 1.82 0.630
17914,383 1,356 5,156 5,729 33%6,775 25%8,031 1.86 0.630
18014,475 1,558 5,265 5,850 37%7,078 28%8,391 1.91 0.630
18044,488 1,536 5,280 5,866 36%7,147 27%8,472 1.92 0.630
18114,479 1,533 5,269 5,855 36%7,232 26%8,573 1.95 0.630
18214,326 1,434 5,090 5,656 35%7,123 25%8,443 1.98 0.629
18314,201 1,429 4,943 5,492 36%7,049 25%8,356 2.02 0.628
18414,168 1,434 4,903 5,448 37%7,125 25%8,445 2.06 0.627
YearGross domestic product of the shogunate domainTaxation rate (Collected tax over the gross domestic product) of the shogunate domain(Gross domestic product of the shogunate domain)/ (Gross domestic product of the national level)Gross domestic product of the national levelPopulationGross domestic product of the national level per capita
Thousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollarsThousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars
Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousandskoku1 koku= 272.31 dollars
l(=i/k)mn(=1.25b/l)qr(=l/q)stu=r/tv=s/t
160017,000
16576,607 1,799,114 21%0.1351,494 14,022,262 23,732 2.17591
16626,216 1,692,612 22%0.1348,445 13,192,191 24,322 1.99542
16716,843 1,863,356 21%0.1353,332 14,522,965 25,385 2.10572
16817,929 2,159,133 16%0.1361,798 16,828,245 26,566 2.33633
16919,384 2,555,302 18%0.1373,137 19,915,977 27,747 2.64718
17019,221 2,510,978 15%0.1371,869 19,570,519 28,928 2.48677
171110,066 2,741,172 16%0.1378,457 21,364,644 30,109 2.61710
17219,956 2,711,227 16%0.1377,600 21,131,256 31,290 2.48675
173111,354 3,091,829 15%0.1387,196 23,744,292 31,218 2.79761
174111,802 3,213,794 17%0.1389,326 24,324,247 31,145 2.87781
175111,604 3,159,795 18%0.1386,574 23,574,833 31,073 2.79759
176112,092 3,292,710 17%0.1488,948 24,221,434 31,001 2.87781
177112,142 3,306,438 14%0.1488,082 23,985,505 30,929 2.85776
178112,358 3,365,318 15%0.1488,425 24,079,098 30,856 2.87780
179112,751 3,472,209 13%0.1490,004 24,509,057 30,784 2.92796
180113,320 3,627,042 15%0.1492,767 25,261,482 30,712 3.02823
180413,448 3,662,028 14%0.1493,290 25,403,800 30,690 3.04828
181113,619 3,708,463 14%0.1496,506 26,279,613 30,943 3.12849
182113,428 3,656,544 13%0.1498,174 26,733,652 31,305 3.14854
183113,305 3,623,009 13%0.13100,460 27,356,259 31,667 3.17864
184113,462 3,665,810 13%0.13105,090 28,616,954 32,029 3.28893
YearOutput and tax revenue of the shogunate domain
Officially estimated outputLand tax revenueOfficially estimated output adjusted for allowanceOutput adjusted for oversightEffective tax rate of the agricultural sector, estimated by the shogunateEstimated agricultural outputEffective tax rate of the agricultural sectorSubtotal of the primary sectorNational output of the primary sector per personSectoral composition of the primary sector: (National primary sector output)/(Gross domestic product of the national level)
Thousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand koku
abd(=a/0.85)e(= d/0.9)f(=1.25b/d)gh(=1.25b/g)i(=g/0.8436)jk
16001.80 0.737
16572,925 1,120 3,442 3,824 41%3,824 37%4,533 1.69 0.686
16622,734 1,100 3,217 3,574 43%3,574 38%4,237 1.68 0.682
16712,975 1,131 3,500 3,889 40%3,889 36%4,609 1.66 0.674
16813,401 1,026 4,001 4,446 32%4,446 29%5,270 1.64 0.665
16913,971 1,354 4,672 5,191 36%5,191 33%6,154 1.62 0.656
17013,849 1,115 4,529 5,032 31%5,032 28%5,965 1.60 0.647
17114,144 1,300 4,876 5,417 33%5,417 30%6,422 1.59 0.638
17214,067 1,306 4,784 5,316 34%5,283 31%6,263 1.57 0.629
17314,531 1,365 5,330 5,923 32%6,026 28%7,143 1.60 0.629
17414,586 1,570 5,396 5,995 36%6,265 31%7,426 1.65 0.629
17514,395 1,705 5,170 5,744 41%6,161 35%7,303 1.69 0.629
17614,466 1,680 5,254 5,837 40%6,421 33%7,612 1.73 0.629
17714,376 1,353 5,148 5,720 33%6,449 26%7,645 1.78 0.630
17814,348 1,466 5,116 5,684 36%6,565 28%7,782 1.82 0.630
17914,383 1,356 5,156 5,729 33%6,775 25%8,031 1.86 0.630
18014,475 1,558 5,265 5,850 37%7,078 28%8,391 1.91 0.630
18044,488 1,536 5,280 5,866 36%7,147 27%8,472 1.92 0.630
18114,479 1,533 5,269 5,855 36%7,232 26%8,573 1.95 0.630
18214,326 1,434 5,090 5,656 35%7,123 25%8,443 1.98 0.629
18314,201 1,429 4,943 5,492 36%7,049 25%8,356 2.02 0.628
18414,168 1,434 4,903 5,448 37%7,125 25%8,445 2.06 0.627
YearGross domestic product of the shogunate domainTaxation rate (Collected tax over the gross domestic product) of the shogunate domain(Gross domestic product of the shogunate domain)/ (Gross domestic product of the national level)Gross domestic product of the national levelPopulationGross domestic product of the national level per capita
Thousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollarsThousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars
Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousandskoku1 koku= 272.31 dollars
l(=i/k)mn(=1.25b/l)qr(=l/q)stu=r/tv=s/t
160017,000
16576,607 1,799,114 21%0.1351,494 14,022,262 23,732 2.17591
16626,216 1,692,612 22%0.1348,445 13,192,191 24,322 1.99542
16716,843 1,863,356 21%0.1353,332 14,522,965 25,385 2.10572
16817,929 2,159,133 16%0.1361,798 16,828,245 26,566 2.33633
16919,384 2,555,302 18%0.1373,137 19,915,977 27,747 2.64718
17019,221 2,510,978 15%0.1371,869 19,570,519 28,928 2.48677
171110,066 2,741,172 16%0.1378,457 21,364,644 30,109 2.61710
17219,956 2,711,227 16%0.1377,600 21,131,256 31,290 2.48675
173111,354 3,091,829 15%0.1387,196 23,744,292 31,218 2.79761
174111,802 3,213,794 17%0.1389,326 24,324,247 31,145 2.87781
175111,604 3,159,795 18%0.1386,574 23,574,833 31,073 2.79759
176112,092 3,292,710 17%0.1488,948 24,221,434 31,001 2.87781
177112,142 3,306,438 14%0.1488,082 23,985,505 30,929 2.85776
178112,358 3,365,318 15%0.1488,425 24,079,098 30,856 2.87780
179112,751 3,472,209 13%0.1490,004 24,509,057 30,784 2.92796
180113,320 3,627,042 15%0.1492,767 25,261,482 30,712 3.02823
180413,448 3,662,028 14%0.1493,290 25,403,800 30,690 3.04828
181113,619 3,708,463 14%0.1496,506 26,279,613 30,943 3.12849
182113,428 3,656,544 13%0.1498,174 26,733,652 31,305 3.14854
183113,305 3,623,009 13%0.13100,460 27,356,259 31,667 3.17864
184113,462 3,665,810 13%0.13105,090 28,616,954 32,029 3.28893

Notes: We convert koku to 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollar by applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars. The grossly failed harvest years 1651 and 1661 are replaced by 1657 and 1662. See Supplementary Appendix A.II. for 1651 and 1661.

Table 5.

Our Estimate of Gross Domestic Product in Early Modern Times, 1651‒1841

YearOutput and tax revenue of the shogunate domain
Officially estimated outputLand tax revenueOfficially estimated output adjusted for allowanceOutput adjusted for oversightEffective tax rate of the agricultural sector, estimated by the shogunateEstimated agricultural outputEffective tax rate of the agricultural sectorSubtotal of the primary sectorNational output of the primary sector per personSectoral composition of the primary sector: (National primary sector output)/(Gross domestic product of the national level)
Thousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand koku
abd(=a/0.85)e(= d/0.9)f(=1.25b/d)gh(=1.25b/g)i(=g/0.8436)jk
16001.80 0.737
16572,925 1,120 3,442 3,824 41%3,824 37%4,533 1.69 0.686
16622,734 1,100 3,217 3,574 43%3,574 38%4,237 1.68 0.682
16712,975 1,131 3,500 3,889 40%3,889 36%4,609 1.66 0.674
16813,401 1,026 4,001 4,446 32%4,446 29%5,270 1.64 0.665
16913,971 1,354 4,672 5,191 36%5,191 33%6,154 1.62 0.656
17013,849 1,115 4,529 5,032 31%5,032 28%5,965 1.60 0.647
17114,144 1,300 4,876 5,417 33%5,417 30%6,422 1.59 0.638
17214,067 1,306 4,784 5,316 34%5,283 31%6,263 1.57 0.629
17314,531 1,365 5,330 5,923 32%6,026 28%7,143 1.60 0.629
17414,586 1,570 5,396 5,995 36%6,265 31%7,426 1.65 0.629
17514,395 1,705 5,170 5,744 41%6,161 35%7,303 1.69 0.629
17614,466 1,680 5,254 5,837 40%6,421 33%7,612 1.73 0.629
17714,376 1,353 5,148 5,720 33%6,449 26%7,645 1.78 0.630
17814,348 1,466 5,116 5,684 36%6,565 28%7,782 1.82 0.630
17914,383 1,356 5,156 5,729 33%6,775 25%8,031 1.86 0.630
18014,475 1,558 5,265 5,850 37%7,078 28%8,391 1.91 0.630
18044,488 1,536 5,280 5,866 36%7,147 27%8,472 1.92 0.630
18114,479 1,533 5,269 5,855 36%7,232 26%8,573 1.95 0.630
18214,326 1,434 5,090 5,656 35%7,123 25%8,443 1.98 0.629
18314,201 1,429 4,943 5,492 36%7,049 25%8,356 2.02 0.628
18414,168 1,434 4,903 5,448 37%7,125 25%8,445 2.06 0.627
YearGross domestic product of the shogunate domainTaxation rate (Collected tax over the gross domestic product) of the shogunate domain(Gross domestic product of the shogunate domain)/ (Gross domestic product of the national level)Gross domestic product of the national levelPopulationGross domestic product of the national level per capita
Thousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollarsThousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars
Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousandskoku1 koku= 272.31 dollars
l(=i/k)mn(=1.25b/l)qr(=l/q)stu=r/tv=s/t
160017,000
16576,607 1,799,114 21%0.1351,494 14,022,262 23,732 2.17591
16626,216 1,692,612 22%0.1348,445 13,192,191 24,322 1.99542
16716,843 1,863,356 21%0.1353,332 14,522,965 25,385 2.10572
16817,929 2,159,133 16%0.1361,798 16,828,245 26,566 2.33633
16919,384 2,555,302 18%0.1373,137 19,915,977 27,747 2.64718
17019,221 2,510,978 15%0.1371,869 19,570,519 28,928 2.48677
171110,066 2,741,172 16%0.1378,457 21,364,644 30,109 2.61710
17219,956 2,711,227 16%0.1377,600 21,131,256 31,290 2.48675
173111,354 3,091,829 15%0.1387,196 23,744,292 31,218 2.79761
174111,802 3,213,794 17%0.1389,326 24,324,247 31,145 2.87781
175111,604 3,159,795 18%0.1386,574 23,574,833 31,073 2.79759
176112,092 3,292,710 17%0.1488,948 24,221,434 31,001 2.87781
177112,142 3,306,438 14%0.1488,082 23,985,505 30,929 2.85776
178112,358 3,365,318 15%0.1488,425 24,079,098 30,856 2.87780
179112,751 3,472,209 13%0.1490,004 24,509,057 30,784 2.92796
180113,320 3,627,042 15%0.1492,767 25,261,482 30,712 3.02823
180413,448 3,662,028 14%0.1493,290 25,403,800 30,690 3.04828
181113,619 3,708,463 14%0.1496,506 26,279,613 30,943 3.12849
182113,428 3,656,544 13%0.1498,174 26,733,652 31,305 3.14854
183113,305 3,623,009 13%0.13100,460 27,356,259 31,667 3.17864
184113,462 3,665,810 13%0.13105,090 28,616,954 32,029 3.28893
YearOutput and tax revenue of the shogunate domain
Officially estimated outputLand tax revenueOfficially estimated output adjusted for allowanceOutput adjusted for oversightEffective tax rate of the agricultural sector, estimated by the shogunateEstimated agricultural outputEffective tax rate of the agricultural sectorSubtotal of the primary sectorNational output of the primary sector per personSectoral composition of the primary sector: (National primary sector output)/(Gross domestic product of the national level)
Thousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand kokuThousand koku
abd(=a/0.85)e(= d/0.9)f(=1.25b/d)gh(=1.25b/g)i(=g/0.8436)jk
16001.80 0.737
16572,925 1,120 3,442 3,824 41%3,824 37%4,533 1.69 0.686
16622,734 1,100 3,217 3,574 43%3,574 38%4,237 1.68 0.682
16712,975 1,131 3,500 3,889 40%3,889 36%4,609 1.66 0.674
16813,401 1,026 4,001 4,446 32%4,446 29%5,270 1.64 0.665
16913,971 1,354 4,672 5,191 36%5,191 33%6,154 1.62 0.656
17013,849 1,115 4,529 5,032 31%5,032 28%5,965 1.60 0.647
17114,144 1,300 4,876 5,417 33%5,417 30%6,422 1.59 0.638
17214,067 1,306 4,784 5,316 34%5,283 31%6,263 1.57 0.629
17314,531 1,365 5,330 5,923 32%6,026 28%7,143 1.60 0.629
17414,586 1,570 5,396 5,995 36%6,265 31%7,426 1.65 0.629
17514,395 1,705 5,170 5,744 41%6,161 35%7,303 1.69 0.629
17614,466 1,680 5,254 5,837 40%6,421 33%7,612 1.73 0.629
17714,376 1,353 5,148 5,720 33%6,449 26%7,645 1.78 0.630
17814,348 1,466 5,116 5,684 36%6,565 28%7,782 1.82 0.630
17914,383 1,356 5,156 5,729 33%6,775 25%8,031 1.86 0.630
18014,475 1,558 5,265 5,850 37%7,078 28%8,391 1.91 0.630
18044,488 1,536 5,280 5,866 36%7,147 27%8,472 1.92 0.630
18114,479 1,533 5,269 5,855 36%7,232 26%8,573 1.95 0.630
18214,326 1,434 5,090 5,656 35%7,123 25%8,443 1.98 0.629
18314,201 1,429 4,943 5,492 36%7,049 25%8,356 2.02 0.628
18414,168 1,434 4,903 5,448 37%7,125 25%8,445 2.06 0.627
YearGross domestic product of the shogunate domainTaxation rate (Collected tax over the gross domestic product) of the shogunate domain(Gross domestic product of the shogunate domain)/ (Gross domestic product of the national level)Gross domestic product of the national levelPopulationGross domestic product of the national level per capita
Thousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollarsThousands of 1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars1990 Geary-Khamis international dollars
Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousand koku1 koku=272.31 dollars Thousandskoku1 koku= 272.31 dollars
l(=i/k)mn(=1.25b/l)qr(=l/q)stu=r/tv=s/t
160017,000
16576,607 1,799,114 21%0.1351,494 14,022,262 23,732 2.17591
16626,216 1,692,612 22%0.1348,445 13,192,191 24,322 1.99542
16716,843 1,863,356 21%0.1353,332 14,522,965 25,385 2.10572
16817,929 2,159,133 16%0.1361,798 16,828,245 26,566 2.33633
16919,384 2,555,302 18%0.1373,137 19,915,977 27,747 2.64718
17019,221 2,510,978 15%0.1371,869 19,570,519 28,928 2.48677
171110,066 2,741,172 16%0.1378,457 21,364,644 30,109 2.61710
17219,956 2,711,227 16%0.1377,600 21,131,256 31,290 2.48675
173111,354 3,091,829 15%0.1387,196 23,744,292 31,218 2.79761
174111,802 3,213,794 17%0.1389,326 24,324,247 31,145 2.87781
175111,604 3,159,795 18%0.1386,574 23,574,833 31,073 2.79759
176112,092 3,292,710 17%0.1488,948 24,221,434 31,001 2.87781
177112,142 3,306,438 14%0.1488,082 23,985,505 30,929 2.85776
178112,358 3,365,318 15%0.1488,425 24,079,098 30,856 2.87780
179112,751 3,472,209 13%0.1490,004 24,509,057 30,784 2.92796
180113,320 3,627,042 15%0.1492,767 25,261,482 30,712 3.02823
180413,448 3,662,028 14%0.1493,290 25,403,800 30,690 3.04828
181113,619 3,708,463 14%0.1496,506 26,279,613 30,943 3.12849
182113,428 3,656,544 13%0.1498,174 26,733,652 31,305 3.14854
183113,305 3,623,009 13%0.13100,460 27,356,259 31,667 3.17864
184113,462 3,665,810 13%0.13105,090 28,616,954 32,029 3.28893

Notes: We convert koku to 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollar by applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars. The grossly failed harvest years 1651 and 1661 are replaced by 1657 and 1662. See Supplementary Appendix A.II. for 1651 and 1661.

Gross Domestic Product, 1651–1841. Source: Supplementary Appendix A.II. Notes: We convert the output in koku to the output in 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars by applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars.
Figure 7.

Gross Domestic Product, 1651–1841. Source: Supplementary Appendix A.II. Notes: We convert the output in koku to the output in 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars by applying 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international Geary–Khamis dollars.

3.3. State Capacity

The shogunate usually only taxed the agricultural sector. The primary tax was the land tax, which was called hon nengu (primary tax). In addition, miscellaneous taxes were levied. The total amount of tax on farmers was roughly 1.25 times the land tax. Thus, we obtain the estimated effective taxation rate of the agricultural output based on the shogunate’s output estimate as series f(=1.25b/d), the estimated effective agricultural taxation rate as series h(=1.25b/g), and the taxation rate of the total output in the shogunate domain as series n(=1.25b/l) in Supplementary Appendix A.II. Figure 8 illustrates the series.

Taxation Rate of the Shogunate Domain, 1651–1841. Source: Supplementary Appendix A.II.
Figure 8.

Taxation Rate of the Shogunate Domain, 1651–1841. Source: Supplementary Appendix A.II.

In the 17th century, when the shogunate conducted a cadastral survey, specified a farming family for each parcel of farmland, and vested the family with property rights for the parcel, the agricultural taxation rate hit 35%; the state capacity, which is measured by the taxation rate of the total output, hit 20%. After the shogunate adopted a fixed amount of taxation in the early 18th century, it failed to raise tax in relation to productivity. The taxation rate of the total output fell to 13% in the mid-19th century.

The state capacity of other domains was not significantly different from the shogunate domain. For instance, in the Kumamoto domain, ruled by Lord Hosokawa, the state capacity is estimated to have been 14–15% from the mid-19th century onwards. The state capacity in the Choshu domain, which was ruled by Lord Mouri and which taxed the secondary and primary sectors, is estimated to have been 21.6% from the mid-19th century onwards (Imamura and Nakabayashi 2017: 38).

However, the state capacity of 13% was much higher than the 8% in China and Turkey (Deng 2012: 342; Pamuk 2012: 321). The state capacity of England rose from less than 10% in the mid-19th century to about 20% during the Napoleonic Wars, and 13% in 1819 after the wars. This enabled the British crown to support infrastructure improvements, notably for the defence of the country (O’Brien and Hunt 1993: 175; Daunton 2012: 112). In Japan, the state capacity of 13% was inherited by the imperial government after the Meiji Restoration and the tax financed modernisation efforts.

4. Quantitative Summary

4.1. Trajectory of Output per Person

For an overview of the performance of the Japanese economy after the seventh century, let us calculate the per capita GDP. Combining the estimates of the population in Table 1 and the output in Tables 3 and 4, we obtain the per capita GDP, as shown in Table 6.

Table 6.

Gross Domestic Product Per Head, 730–1874

JapanChinaGreat BritainGermanyPortugalPoland
GDPPopulationPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDP
Our EstimateBassino et al. (2019)
Million kokuMillionkoku1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar
aba/b
7308.6936.1001.425388376
95010.9245.0002.185595635
980853
10201,006
1050967
1086878723
1120863
11507.2623.9001.862507583
128011.6005.9501.950531529651
1300724742
14001,0321,045742562
145020.21210.0502.0115485459901,011
15008581,0681,146702
1550836
15708851,096
160041.60017.0002.4476666678651,077807790810
16502.1705911,055830
17002.4356631,1031,563939987569
17202.4836769501,605
172177.60031.2902.480675675
17502.7807577271,7101,0501,371
18003.0298256142,080986916
180493.30030.6903.040828828
18203.129852634
1846106.90032.2103.319904903
18506002,997923
18706183,8561,692946
1874129.54134.8403.7181,0121,011
JapanChinaGreat BritainGermanyPortugalPoland
GDPPopulationPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDP
Our EstimateBassino et al. (2019)
Million kokuMillionkoku1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar
aba/b
7308.6936.1001.425388376
95010.9245.0002.185595635
980853
10201,006
1050967
1086878723
1120863
11507.2623.9001.862507583
128011.6005.9501.950531529651
1300724742
14001,0321,045742562
145020.21210.0502.0115485459901,011
15008581,0681,146702
1550836
15708851,096
160041.60017.0002.4476666678651,077807790810
16502.1705911,055830
17002.4356631,1031,563939987569
17202.4836769501,605
172177.60031.2902.480675675
17502.7807577271,7101,0501,371
18003.0298256142,080986916
180493.30030.6903.040828828
18203.129852634
1846106.90032.2103.319904903
18506002,997923
18706183,8561,692946
1874129.54134.8403.7181,0121,011

Notes: We convert Japan’s per capita GDP in terms of koku into that of 1990 Geary–Khamis international dollars using 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international G-K dollars.

Source: For Japan: Tables 1, 3, 34, and Supplementary Appendix A.II. The value for 1650 is the estimate for 1657 in Supplementary Appendix A.II. For Great Britain and China: Bassino et al. (2019: 19); for Germany: Malinowski and van Zanden (2017) and Palma and Reis (2019); for Portugal, Palma and Reis (2019); and for Poland, Malinowski and van Zanden (2017).

Table 6.

Gross Domestic Product Per Head, 730–1874

JapanChinaGreat BritainGermanyPortugalPoland
GDPPopulationPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDP
Our EstimateBassino et al. (2019)
Million kokuMillionkoku1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar
aba/b
7308.6936.1001.425388376
95010.9245.0002.185595635
980853
10201,006
1050967
1086878723
1120863
11507.2623.9001.862507583
128011.6005.9501.950531529651
1300724742
14001,0321,045742562
145020.21210.0502.0115485459901,011
15008581,0681,146702
1550836
15708851,096
160041.60017.0002.4476666678651,077807790810
16502.1705911,055830
17002.4356631,1031,563939987569
17202.4836769501,605
172177.60031.2902.480675675
17502.7807577271,7101,0501,371
18003.0298256142,080986916
180493.30030.6903.040828828
18203.129852634
1846106.90032.2103.319904903
18506002,997923
18706183,8561,692946
1874129.54134.8403.7181,0121,011
JapanChinaGreat BritainGermanyPortugalPoland
GDPPopulationPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDPPer Capita GDP
Our EstimateBassino et al. (2019)
Million kokuMillionkoku1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary– Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar1990 International Geary–Khamis Dollar
aba/b
7308.6936.1001.425388376
95010.9245.0002.185595635
980853
10201,006
1050967
1086878723
1120863
11507.2623.9001.862507583
128011.6005.9501.950531529651
1300724742
14001,0321,045742562
145020.21210.0502.0115485459901,011
15008581,0681,146702
1550836
15708851,096
160041.60017.0002.4476666678651,077807790810
16502.1705911,055830
17002.4356631,1031,563939987569
17202.4836769501,605
172177.60031.2902.480675675
17502.7807577271,7101,0501,371
18003.0298256142,080986916
180493.30030.6903.040828828
18203.129852634
1846106.90032.2103.319904903
18506002,997923
18706183,8561,692946
1874129.54134.8403.7181,0121,011

Notes: We convert Japan’s per capita GDP in terms of koku into that of 1990 Geary–Khamis international dollars using 1 koku = 272.31 1990 international G-K dollars.

Source: For Japan: Tables 1, 3, 34, and Supplementary Appendix A.II. The value for 1650 is the estimate for 1657 in Supplementary Appendix A.II. For Great Britain and China: Bassino et al. (2019: 19); for Germany: Malinowski and van Zanden (2017) and Palma and Reis (2019); for Portugal, Palma and Reis (2019); and for Poland, Malinowski and van Zanden (2017).

As the series shows, Japan’s per capita GDP grew from the eighth century to the 10th but declined in the 12th, primarily because of climate cooling (Midorikawa 2019; Supplementary Appendix A.I.2). Our substantial downward revision of the per capita GDP in 1150 from Bassino et al. (2019) is driven by the update of total output based on Midorikawa (2019), as discussed in section 2. It then began to recover from the late 13th century and regained its former glory in the late 15th century. It fell briefly due to population growth in the early 17th century but began to increase again in the late 17th century.

Japan’s GDP surpassed China’s in the 18th century for the first time in its history. It grew closer to peripheral European countries such as Poland and Portugal by the early-19th century. However, the West, led by Britain, further accelerated productivity growth from the early-19th century. The development that followed the Napoleonic wars left Japan far behind England.

In terms of improving resource allocation within each nation-state, the shogunate regime that protected property rights under the stable state was effective. However, its isolationist policy placed Japan behind the West when the West was realising the first age of globalisation from the mid-19th century, which strengthened knowledge spill-over. The labour intensive technology mix in the early modern period would not have enabled Japan to catch up with the Western advanced economies on its own (Kumon 2020). Without the Meiji Restoration of 1868 to open the country, Japan would have been unable to compete with advanced economies (Schreurs 2019; Vries 2020: 38–41; Broadberry and Fukao (Forthcoming)).

4.2. Price Responsiveness of Agricultural Output in the Early Modern Period

Our emphasis on property rights protection by the shogunate and lords since the 17th century implicitly assumes that farmers were exposed to the market and exerted residual control on how to use their parcel of farmland to maximise their utility. Property rights protection would improve resource allocation because property rights holders would exercise residual control rights to maximise the income they earn. This story envisages that sellers in markets would use their assets to maximise their profits. If this assumption held true, then the agricultural output would respond to prices in the market. Case studies have shown that early modern farmers were active market participants as the sellers of crops and, in the case of landlords, investors in rice-denominated lords’ bills in the Dojima Rice Exchange (Takatsuki 2012: 26–68). We examine whether such price responsiveness was a nation-wide phenomenon, so that property rights protection could affect the decision-making of the farmers’ class.

We use the series of the agricultural output of the shogunate domain (g in Supplementary Appendix A.II) and of the rice price at Osaka market available from 1701 (Supplementary Appendix A.II) to quantify the lead-lag relationship between the agricultural output and the price of rice in the shogunate domain. We use the first differences to remove possible trends. As the vector autoregression of the first difference of agricultural output (Δoutputt=outputtoutputt1) and that of the rice price for Osaka (Δpricet =pricetpricet1) shows, output changes depended on prices changes, while prices barely depended on output (Table 7). This tendency is summarised as the Granger causality only from price changes to output changes (Table 8).

Table 7.

Vector Autoregression of Agricultural Output of the Shogunate Domain and Rice Price at Osaka

Dependent VariableΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat
Coefficientz StatisticsCoefficientz Statistics
Δoutputt-1−0.07−0.870.000.7
Δoutputt-20.182.22**0.001.88*
Δprice_osakat-1−454.89−1.66*−0.31−3.83***
Δprice_osakat-2−787.77−2.89***−0.33−4.11***
χ 214.29*** 28.53***
R  20.09 0.17
Sample period1704‒1841
Log likelihood−2,311.18
Number of observations138
Akaike Information Criterion33.61
Dependent VariableΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat
Coefficientz StatisticsCoefficientz Statistics
Δoutputt-1−0.07−0.870.000.7
Δoutputt-20.182.22**0.001.88*
Δprice_osakat-1−454.89−1.66*−0.31−3.83***
Δprice_osakat-2−787.77−2.89***−0.33−4.11***
χ 214.29*** 28.53***
R  20.09 0.17
Sample period1704‒1841
Log likelihood−2,311.18
Number of observations138
Akaike Information Criterion33.61

Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Table 7.

Vector Autoregression of Agricultural Output of the Shogunate Domain and Rice Price at Osaka

Dependent VariableΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat
Coefficientz StatisticsCoefficientz Statistics
Δoutputt-1−0.07−0.870.000.7
Δoutputt-20.182.22**0.001.88*
Δprice_osakat-1−454.89−1.66*−0.31−3.83***
Δprice_osakat-2−787.77−2.89***−0.33−4.11***
χ 214.29*** 28.53***
R  20.09 0.17
Sample period1704‒1841
Log likelihood−2,311.18
Number of observations138
Akaike Information Criterion33.61
Dependent VariableΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat
Coefficientz StatisticsCoefficientz Statistics
Δoutputt-1−0.07−0.870.000.7
Δoutputt-20.182.22**0.001.88*
Δprice_osakat-1−454.89−1.66*−0.31−3.83***
Δprice_osakat-2−787.77−2.89***−0.33−4.11***
χ 214.29*** 28.53***
R  20.09 0.17
Sample period1704‒1841
Log likelihood−2,311.18
Number of observations138
Akaike Information Criterion33.61

Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Table 8.

Granger Causality Walt Test for Agricultural Output of the Shogunate Domain and Rice Price at Osaka

Dependent VariablesExcludedχ 2Lags
ΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat9.42***2
ΔPrice_osakatΔOutputt3.852
Dependent VariablesExcludedχ 2Lags
ΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat9.42***2
ΔPrice_osakatΔOutputt3.852

Note: *** indicates significance at the 1% level.

Table 8.

Granger Causality Walt Test for Agricultural Output of the Shogunate Domain and Rice Price at Osaka

Dependent VariablesExcludedχ 2Lags
ΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat9.42***2
ΔPrice_osakatΔOutputt3.852
Dependent VariablesExcludedχ 2Lags
ΔOutputtΔPrice_osakat9.42***2
ΔPrice_osakatΔOutputt3.852

Note: *** indicates significance at the 1% level.

In some domains, the lord designated specific crops and committed to the purchase of these crops, called the lord’s monopsony and monopoly. In such cases, the residual control rights of owner-farmers over their parcels of farmland were restricted. Otherwise, registered owner-farmers assumed residual control over the parcels they cultivated, which allowed them to decide on crop choice and resource allocation. In the shogunate domain, since the shogunate did not impose a monopsony or monopoly policy, the farmers controlled decision-making. The results of the vector autoregression of the output and prices indicate that farmers were highly responsive to the prices of products when they allocated resources at their discretion.

Here, we assume the division of labour within the peasant economy as described by Saito (1983, 1998, 2000, 2009). We characterise Saito’s description as follows: Farming household i has a resource endowment of farmland it owned (Ki) and the family labour it fed (Li). We standardise family labour endowment such that Li = 1. Let lr,i  1 denote labour retained at home, where subscript r refers to retained.

As Saito argues, each farming household retained lr,i  to meet the demand in the busiest farming seasons. That is, each household had some slack part of lr,i for some days within a year. A temporary slack portion of lr,i would be hired by another farming household. A temporary slack portion of the workforce retained at home is used by the real agricultural wage wa. Within the village, transfer of wa among households is cancelled out. If the farming household was the maximiser of the household revenue and exposed to the regional labour market, the operation rate of the workforce retained at home would monotonically increase with wa. Then, the effective labour supply to agriculture at household i is approximately lai=walr, i.

We approximate the agricultural output of household i by ya,i=Ala,iβ Ki1β =Awaβlr,iβKi1β where 0 < β < 1, that is, the returns on land and labour are marginally decreasing. A denotes labour productivity measured by the amount of agricultural output. Household i allocates labour 1lr,i to the non-farm sector side jobs. Labour allocation to the non-farm sector included, for instance, hand weaving by female family members in the summer and winter and males working at a sake brewery in the winter. Let wu denote the real wage for casual labour in the urban sector where u refers to urban, deflated by the consumption goods price. Farming households i maximised their revenue Ri=pya,i+wu(1lr,i), where p denotes the relative price of agricultural products over manufactured goods, by optimising their labour inputs to the agricultural sector, lr,i and the non-farm sector, 1  lr,i.

Since Ri=pya,i+wu(1lr,i)=pAwaβlr,iβKi1βwulr,i+wu, the first-order condition for the maximisation of revenue implies that the optimal allocation of family labour to the agricultural sector is lr,i=A11ββ11βKip11βwaβ1βwu11β.

Thus, optimal labour allocation to agriculture lr,i increases with the labour productivity of agriculture A, the relative price of agricultural products p, and the agricultural wage wa, but decreases with the non-farm urban wage wu. If farming households, in general, followed this strategy, then the agricultural output would increase with the labour productivity of agriculture, the price of the agricultural products, and the agricultural wage wa, but decrease with the urban wage wu.

Thus, to test our prediction, we perform the following ordinary least squares regressions:

(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)

where t is the time trend, pr,t is the relative price of rice over the average price of manufactured goods in period t, and pc,t is the relative price of raw cotton over that of manufactured goods.

For agricultural output ya, we use the output of the shogunate domain, series g in Supplementary Appendix A.II. For agriculture productivity AK, we use the agricultural output per person at the national level, series j in Supplementary Appendix A.II. For the relative price of rice pr, we divide the rice price in Osaka by the price of manufactured goods in the Osaka and Kyoto regions. For the relative price of raw cotton, we divide the raw cotton price in the Osaka region by the price index of manufactured goods in the Osaka and Kyoto regions. For real agricultural wages wa, we use the real daily wage of day workers in the agricultural sector in the Kinai region. For the urban wage wu, we use the real daily wage of day workers in Kyoto. All of the above are shown in Supplementary Appendix A.II.

Equation (1) quantifies the agricultural output’s response to the relative rice price pr,t and real wages in the agricultural sector wa,t. Equation (2) measures the agricultural output’s response to the relative raw cotton price pc,t and real wages in the agricultural sector wa,t. In both equations, assuming that the farming household maximised its revenue, we predict significantly positive values for α3 and α4.

Equation (3) tests whether the agricultural output responded to the relative raw cotton price pc,t and real wages in the urban sector wu,t. Equation (4) checks whether the agricultural output responded to the relative raw cotton price pc,t and real wages in the urban sector wu,t. In both equations, the coefficients of interest are α3 and α4. Assuming that the farming household maximised its revenue, we predict a significantly positive α3. If the local labour markets were tightly connected with the urban labour markets, we predict a significantly negative α4. The results are shown in Table 9.

Table 9.

Response of Agricultural Output to Rice Price and Relative Wage in the Shogunate Domain

9–19–29–39–4
Dependent Variablelog (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)
Coefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt Statistics
Constant14.9273.83***14.2483.88***14.0299.55***13.5388.82***
t0.00−1.97*−0.01−7.52***−0.01−8.79***−0.01−12.50***
log (productivityt)2.003.03***4.448.48***4.9410.39***6.5013.61***
 log (pr, t)0.021.69*−0.01−0.80
 log (pc, t)0.022.06**0.011.12
 log (wa, t)0.041.74*0.1510.77***
 log (wu, t)−0.04−2.66***−0.01−0.83
Degrees of freedom75446445
 Adjusted R20.920.960.940.90
F statistics226.4***286.7***248.8***113.2***
9–19–29–39–4
Dependent Variablelog (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)
Coefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt Statistics
Constant14.9273.83***14.2483.88***14.0299.55***13.5388.82***
t0.00−1.97*−0.01−7.52***−0.01−8.79***−0.01−12.50***
log (productivityt)2.003.03***4.448.48***4.9410.39***6.5013.61***
 log (pr, t)0.021.69*−0.01−0.80
 log (pc, t)0.022.06**0.011.12
 log (wa, t)0.041.74*0.1510.77***
 log (wu, t)−0.04−2.66***−0.01−0.83
Degrees of freedom75446445
 Adjusted R20.920.960.940.90
F statistics226.4***286.7***248.8***113.2***

Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

Table 9.

Response of Agricultural Output to Rice Price and Relative Wage in the Shogunate Domain

9–19–29–39–4
Dependent Variablelog (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)
Coefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt Statistics
Constant14.9273.83***14.2483.88***14.0299.55***13.5388.82***
t0.00−1.97*−0.01−7.52***−0.01−8.79***−0.01−12.50***
log (productivityt)2.003.03***4.448.48***4.9410.39***6.5013.61***
 log (pr, t)0.021.69*−0.01−0.80
 log (pc, t)0.022.06**0.011.12
 log (wa, t)0.041.74*0.1510.77***
 log (wu, t)−0.04−2.66***−0.01−0.83
Degrees of freedom75446445
 Adjusted R20.920.960.940.90
F statistics226.4***286.7***248.8***113.2***
9–19–29–39–4
Dependent Variablelog (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)log (ya, t)
Coefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt StatisticsCoefficientt Statistics
Constant14.9273.83***14.2483.88***14.0299.55***13.5388.82***
t0.00−1.97*−0.01−7.52***−0.01−8.79***−0.01−12.50***
log (productivityt)2.003.03***4.448.48***4.9410.39***6.5013.61***
 log (pr, t)0.021.69*−0.01−0.80
 log (pc, t)0.022.06**0.011.12
 log (wa, t)0.041.74*0.1510.77***
 log (wu, t)−0.04−2.66***−0.01−0.83
Degrees of freedom75446445
 Adjusted R20.920.960.940.90
F statistics226.4***286.7***248.8***113.2***

Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.

In specification 9–1, the relative rice price pr and the real agricultural wage wa have a significantly positive coefficient, as predicted. A 1% increase in the relative price of rice raised agricultural output by 2% and a 1% increase in the real agricultural wage did by 4%. In specification 9–2, the relative price of raw cotton pc and real agricultural wage wa have significantly positive coefficients, as predicted. A 1% rise in the relative price in raw cotton raised agricultural output by 2%. The results are consistent with our prediction that farming households optimise labour allocation, pricing in the rice market, and pricing in the labour market to maximise household revenue.

The results in specifications 9–3 and 9–4 are mixed. In specification 9–3, the real urban wage has a significantly negative coefficient, which shows that a 1% increase in the real urban wage decreased agricultural output by 4%, consistent with our prediction. However, the relative price of raw cotton does not have a significant coefficient. In specification 9–4, neither the relative price of raw cotton nor the real urban wage has a significant coefficient.

Our empirical results show that farming households keenly responded to the price changes of rice, raw cotton, local labour, and, to some extent, urban labour markets. Our agricultural output data cannot differentiate the output of rice and that of raw cotton. We thus fail to identify the effects of relative prices of rice and raw cotton on the optimisation behaviour of farming households. Still, our empirical results are consistent with Saito’s argument that the peasant economy optimises internal labour allocation as a response to the goods and labour markets.

5 Institutional Changes

5.1. The Rise and Demise of the Manorial System

From the sixth century onwards, the imperial family had been actively introducing Chinese institutions and technologies to reinforce its domestic rule. The imperial court completed its Sinisation efforts by enacting the Taiho Imperial Legal Code (Taihō Ritsu Ryō) of 701. This legal code introduced an ideal type of centralised Chinese administration and ownership and also denied any right to private property—that is, any claim to residuals to be assumed by subordinate stakeholders. This had a devastating effect on agriculture because it discouraged local rulers from reclaiming and maintaining farmland.

Responding to the setback, the imperial court promulgated the Three Generation Usufruct Act (San Se Isshin no Hō) of 723, which allowed the developer of a parcel of paddy fields to use the parcel for three generations. The imperial court also promulgated the Privatisation of Reclaimed Lands in Perpetuity Act (Konden Einen Shizai Hō) of 743, which allowed a developer of a parcel of paddy fields to own the parcel privately without a specified duration.

The 743 Act required the registration of newly reclaimed parcels of paddy fields at the imperial court for private ownership. When the imperial court approved a request for private ownership of a newly reclaimed parcel, the imperial court delegated the administrative and judicial authority to the developer as well. The parcel, whose private ownership was warranted and whose governance was delegated, was called a shōen (manor or estate). This system of decentralised ownership and delegated governance was the manorial system (Nishitani, Hayashima and Nakabayashi 2017; Piggott 2018).

The 743 Act prompted large temples and shrines to reclaim paddy fields. This formed the backdrop of a rise in output from the mid-eighth century to the early ninth century (Figure 5). The growth was, however, stunted by the climate cooling from the ninth century to the early 12th century (Midorikawa 2019).

The retreat stopped in the 12th century because of the cessation of climate cooling and for institutional reasons. While large temples and shrines were the driving force of the reclamation when the Act of 743 came into force, local rulers then rose as developers of paddy fields. A local ruler who reclaimed a parcel of paddy fields ‘donated’ the parcel to a noble, a temple, or a shrine first. Then, the recipient obtained a charter to establish the parcel as a manor from the imperial court, and the manorial lord who obtained the charter ‘appointed’ the local ruler who reclaimed and donated the parcel as a local officer of the manor. Such local rulers were an origin of samurai. The transformation was accompanied by a further decentralisation of governance. Particularly, the Kamakura shogunate, which was the first samurai’s administration, was established to protect the samurai’s claims within the manorial system (Nagahara 1973: 3–53; Nagahara 1975; Friday 2010; Nishitani et al. 2017; Piggott 2018).

By the 14th century, uncultivated land that had been easily reclaimed under the medieval techniques dried up. This meant that the relative price of land over capital and labour rose. Accordingly, more capital- and labour-intensive techniques were adopted to intensify farming. Continuous cropping replaced the existing fallow method. The adoption of indica ‘red’ varieties of the rice plant, which were more resilient to the cold weather, helped enhance intensive farming with continuous cropping (Saito 2002; Saito 2015a; Nishitani 2017; Saito and Takashima 2017a).

A marginal rise in land productivity was earned by the landlord class than by manorial lords. The distribution of income towards manorial lords dropped from about 40~50% until the 12th century to about 30% in the 14th century (Nishitani and Nakabayashi 2017).

The technical transformation in the 14th and 15th centuries was also associated with institutional changes. Intensified farming meant that the manual labour and care supplied by cultivators became critical inputs. Until the 14th century, cultivators were typically subcontractors by annual contracts (Nishitani 2006: 306-351). Along with the prevalence of intensive farming, they settled into a specific place and formed a village community with landlords. Village communities were then placed in charge of handling farmland usage within the village and negotiating with feudal lords. Under such village-contractor system, village communities committed to making lump-sum payments of the stipulated land taxes of the entire village. Meanwhile, the feudal lord who ruled the village did not intervene in the internal affairs of the village if the village paid the stipulated land tax. The possibility of interference, or misdeeds, by the feudal lords was monitored by the nature of the relationship among the parties—by force, if necessary. Medieval farmers were armed with swords and guns; using arms to resolve conflicts was considered legal not only for samurai but for farmers as well (Inaba 2010; Nishitani et al. 2017).

While the village community served as a collective bargaining device against feudal lords, it also worked as an insurance mechanism to shield villagers from free financial markets. The medieval period, notably the 13th to 14th centuries, was Japan’s first age of entirely free financial markets. Without any regulation on interest rates, the most vulnerable agents such as subcontracting cultivators were free to borrow from city financiers by paying extremely high interest rates, such as annual rates of 50–60%. Indebted cultivators sometimes rioted, demanding the shogunate to force financiers to write off debts. Prioritising social stability, the Muromachi shogunate promulgated the Toku Sei Rei (Shogunate Ordinance for Virtuous Governance), which forced financiers to write off debts. Using microfinance to pay the land tax within the village community warded off the violence of unregulated financial markets (Nakabayashi 2020).

Under the village-contractor system in the 15th and 16th centuries, the village community assumed residual control rights of farmland within the village, and the village community was entitled to residuals after paying the stipulated land tax. Thus, under the village-contractor system, farmers jointly assumed the property rights of the farmland they cultivated. The scheme, which provided the village community with strong incentives to improve productivity, was suitable for a transition from extensive to intensive farming. This institutional development was, along with technical improvements, a cause of productivity increases in the 15th and 16th centuries (Table 5).

In the age of provincial wars from the late 15th century onwards, the manorial system faded away. Feudal lords became the sole tax authorities and acted as the ‘state’ (Ferejohn and Rosenbluth 2010), and farmers became the sole claimants to residuals from farming. The decentralisation of power to local rulers and farmers and the changes in income distribution to local rulers and farmers were likely to help the productivity recover from the 13th century and further rise from the 14th century onwards.

5.2. Land Reclamation and Smallholders’ Property Rights

Under the medieval village-contractor system, the property of villagers was jointly protected against possible discretionary taxation by feudal lords. However, as lords were not allowed to intervene in the internal affairs of villages, individual farmers’ rights were vulnerable to possible infringement by fellow farmers in the villages.

A proposal to address this defect was suggested by the administration of Hideyoshi Toyotomi, who reunified Japan in 1590 (Ike 2010). The Toyotomi administration decreed a thorough cadastral survey and the disarmament of farmers. The latter was enacted with peace orders to lords and samurai and to farmers and a ban restricting fisherfolk from picarooning. While all samurai, farmers, and fisherfolk had reserved the right to resolve conflicts with the use of armed force in the medieval period, the Toyotomi administration transformed the regime. The Toyotomi administration established a benefice of lords, property rights of farmers, and fishing rights; however, the protection was conditional on relinquishing the right to use arms to settle disputes, and violations led to punishment by the administration. While the physical disarmament of farmers was not common—most farmers retained their arms—it became illegal for farmers to resort to arms to resolve disagreements with other farmers of neighboring villages, for instance, on water rights. Similarly, the Toyotomi administration assumed supreme command and denied the right of belligerence to the lords. Any act of combat had to be by order of Toyotomi Hideyoshi. In that sense, lords were not independent feudal lords anymore (Hall 1961, 1981; Fujiki 2005).

The cadastral survey complemented the arms ban. The Toyotomi administration instructed lords to survey every single parcel of farmland, specify the family who cultivated the parcel, and vest the family with the property rights of the parcel (Araki 1986[1959]; Hall 1981). In practice, the costly cadastral survey was not fully conducted during the reign of Toyotomi. For the shogunate domain, a full cadastral survey was completed in the 1670s. Then, the property rights of individual farming households were protected by the state (Iwahashi 1999: 98–104). The cadastral survey vested stem peasant families with the property rights of the farmland they cultivated. This was the reason they accepted a high land taxation rate in the 17th century (Figure 8).

Under the Edo shogunate federation, the shogunate acted as a central government, assuming diplomacy and national defence as its purview. It also directly ruled its domain. Local lords operated under the shogunate command for national security, but assumed sovereignty for domestic affairs in their domain, including legislation and taxation. Thus, the shogunate and lords independently chose their own taxation policies (Ravina 1995; Ravina 1999: 16–45; Mitani 2020; Nakabayashi (Forthcoming)).

Residual claims involve a trade-off between incentive and risk. Here the risk borne by the residual claimant is volatility of harvests. On the one hand, this provided residual claimants with incentives to improve productivity. On the other hand, taking risks lowers the expected utility of risk-averse agents. Thus, the protection of the property rights of farmers came with both stronger incentives, promising increased tax revenues in the long term, and compensation for risk-taking, which in practice meant a reduction in taxes. If the former effect dominated the latter, then the protection of exclusive property rights would enhance social welfare and increase tax revenues, and vice versa. That is, whether exclusive property rights should contribute to welfare and tax revenue maximisation depended on the farmers’ tolerance to weather risk—in essence, their agricultural productivity. As a result, the shogunate and lords in developed regions—where productivity was higher, and hence individual farming households were more tolerant to weather risk—adopted property rights protection for individual farming households.

However, lords in backward regions, where productivity was lower—and therefore, individual farming households were more vulnerable to weather risk—maintained joint ownership at the village level. The lord vested a village with property rights over the farmland that the villagers cultivated but did not match a specific parcel of farmland with a household as the household’s property. Instead, the village assigned parcels to households, and if necessary, reallocated parcels. Domains that sustained such joint ownership in some form to some extent amounted to about 30% of the national output officially estimated by the shogunate (koku daka) (Brown 1993: 39–112; Brown 2011: 58–100; Brown 2018).

During the peace of the shogunate federation, land tax revenue was reinvested in the reclamation of paddy fields. The shogunate and the lords assumed exclusive taxation authority, and, hence, had incentives and resources to reclaim uncultivated alluvial plains located in the lower reaches of big rivers (Miyamoto 1999: 41–45). The large investment in the 17th century brought about a surge in output from the 17th century to the early 18th century (Figures 6 and 7).

5.3. The Narrow Path Between Growth and Stability

After the establishment of exclusive property rights of individual stem families, the shogunate had a keen awareness of the trade-offs between growth and social stability. In particular, the shogunate strictly regulated farmland collateral loans for farmers by leaving the contracts beyond village borders, notably from merchants to farmers, outside of possible foreclosure enforcement by the shogunate court. The shogunate attempted to maintain the owner-farmer class (Mandai and Nakabayashi 2017, 2018; Nakabayashi 2020).

The effect of such regulation was substantial. Immediately after the Meiji Restoration of 1868, tenanted farmland represented 27.4% of the national average in 1873. The number was even lower in eastern Japan under the stronger influence of the shogunate. In the Kanto region and the north-eastern region of eastern Japan, the rates were 23.6% and 14.6%, respectively (Furushima 1958: 332; Kwon 2002: 72; Vries 2020: 144).

In the 1710–1720s, the shogunate made a transition from fixed-rate taxation to fixed amount taxation. Under the latter, marginal growth in the output entirely belonged to the owner-farmer, and, hence, provided stronger incentives, but also imposed greater risks. To avoid exposing owner-farmers to too many risks, the shogunate temporarily switched back to fixed-rate taxation and, in effect, reduced land taxes when the output was less than 70% of the average years (Oishi 1969[1794]: 188–191).

If the temporary tax reduction by switching to fixed-rate taxation was insufficient, it could result in the organised protests of farmers. The shogunate and lords usually accommodated demands from farmers while they suppressed organisers (White 1995: 1–24).

After the Meiji Restoration, the imperial government enacted the Land Tax Reform Act (Chiso Kaisei Jōrei) of 1873, under which the land tax was a fixed amount, regardless of the yield of the harvest. The imperial government also executed the Ordinance for Pledging Land for Loan and Securing Loan by Land (Jisho Shichiire Kakiire Kisoku) of 1873, which equally protected land-collateral loans either within or beyond village borders. Furthermore, the government did not reduce the land tax in poor harvest years. The outcome was straightforward. The national average ratio of tenanted farmland rose from 27.4% in 1873 to 45.4% in 1908. In particular, those in the Kanto and the north-eastern regions of eastern Japan rose from 23.6% and 14.6% to 46% and 41.6%, respectively (Furushima 1958: 332; Kwon 2002: 115; Francks 2006: 137; Vries 2020: 144).

Under the modern tenancy contract in Japan, consolidation of farmland ownership did not imply a rise in the scale of farming. Typically, ex-owner peasants continued to cultivate the parcels they had owned. Thus, the expansion of landlordism did not accompany changes in agricultural techniques. Instead, it was an institutional change in risk-sharing. When the government ceased to share the risk with farmers, and owner peasants could not bear the weather, financial market, and rice market risks, they transferred their property rights to landlords and continued to cultivate their ex-properties, relying on risk-bearing by landlords (Arimoto 2005; Arimoto, Okazaki and Nakabayashi 2010; Sakane 2014, 2019; Sakane and Arimoto 2017).

The protection of property rights for individual households strengthened incentives for productivity improvements, which led to productivity growth in the 18th century. At the same time, the regulation on farmland-collateral loans was intended to hinder agricultural financial markets from expanding geographically. The regulation, along with flexible taxation, stabilised the peasant economy. This was the backdrop of higher social stability in the early modern period compared with the medieval and modern periods. The effort to balance growth and stability enabled modest, but long-term, growth under the Edo shogunate regime (Saito 2015b; Mandai and Nakabayashi 2018; Schreurs 2019).

6. Conclusion

Fukao et al. (2017a), Fukao et al. (2017b), Takashima (2017), and Bassino et al. (2019) substantially updated Japan’s per capita GDP estimates before the mid-18th century based on historical documents. Here, we have revised the output estimates for the year 1150 based on Midorikawa (2019) and extended the output estimate by incorporating the estimate by Midorikawa (2019). Further, we revised the population estimate for 1150 by Farris (2009) downwards based on Midorikawa (2019).

We have also extended the output estimates for additional points over the centuries by consistently linking the agricultural estimates for the ancient and medieval periods presented by Midorikawa (2019) and records of output in the Edo shogunate domain in the early modern period presented by Ono (1996), Nakabayashi (2012), and Imamura and Nakabayashi (2017) to the estimates by Fukao et al. (2017a), Fukao et al. (2017b), Takashima (2017), and Bassino et al. (2019).

Based on the estimates, we have revised long-term trend of output per person. Notably, we found that medieval Japan reached a low-growth equilibrium in the 12th century under the manorial system, and saw a spike with the emergence of feudal lords from the 13th century onwards, and that further acceleration in the early modern period began in the late 17th century.

Our results also confirm that the new geopolitics and international economy after the Napoleonic Wars had a significant influence. The gap between the leading Western nations and Japan widened again from the early 19th century when the first age of globalisation was integrating Western nations, increasing the division of labour globally, and accelerating knowledge transfer among Western nations (Schreurs 2019; Broadberry and Fukao (Forthcoming)). This widening gap between Japan and a resurging West was seen as a threat by the shogunate in the 19th century, whose crucial moment was the US navy’s visit in 1853. The immediate response of the shogunate was the building of a modern navy, followed by the Meiji Restoration of 1868, which fully opened Japan up to Western knowledge and was essential for sustainable growth.

The productivity growth trajectory drawn by Fukao et al. (2017a), Fukao et al. (2017b), Takashima (2017), and Bassino et al. (2019) shows a rapid rise in the 15th century. Our downward revision for the 12th century and the extension of estimate points indicate that the rise began earlier—from the 13th century—after a sharp fall. This revision is, however, qualitatively consistent with the view suggested by Saito and Takashima (2017a)—that the decentralisation of governance, along with the emergence of the samurai class, led to productivity growth. In the late 13th century the Kamakura shogunate mobilised national resources to defend Japan against the Mongolian invasion, and thus its authority was strengthened over manorial lords such as the imperial family, nobles, temples, and shrines. Backed by the Kamakura shogunate, the samurai gradually established exclusive rule over the benefice territory, eroding the power of the manorial lords. The process accelerated in the 14th and 15th centuries under the Muromachi shogunate (Takahashi 2008: 215–310; Nishitani et al. 2017). The decentralisation of governance, by which we mean the decline of manorial lords and the rise of local samurai rulers, contributed to productivity improvement.

Our finding that the early modern acceleration began in the late 17th century, which was earlier than previously estimated, is also consistent with recent works on Japan’s modernisation after the Meiji Restoration. While the Tokyo Stock Exchange and Osaka Stock Exchange emerged as centres of corporate finance from the 1880s (Nakabayashi 2019a), and the Bank of Japan bolstered the Tokyo and Osaka markets in the 1890s (Nakabayashi 2017a), case studies on growth in regional economies from the 1880s to the 1910s have found that relational corporate finance from local financiers and banks to local entrepreneurs was also one of the driving forces of industrialisation, as well as major organised exchanges and arms-length lending in Tokyo and Osaka. Long-standing resource allocation mechanisms in regional economies bequeathed from a decentralised early modern Japan continued to be an engine of growth until the early 20th century (Nakamura 2000, 2010, 2014, 2015). Also, the key role of the stem family for resource allocation and risk-sharing in the early modern period was formalised after the Meiji Restoration by adopting a continental civil law system (Nakabayashi 2019b). The traditional law affected choice and building of the modern law system as seen in many other industrialised economies (Gutmann and Voigt 2020).

In the manufacturing sector, the highly competitive silk-reeling industry had a long tradition in the early modern period and quickly modernised after the Meiji Restoration (Nakabayashi 2006, 2014, 2017b). In other traditional branches such as weaving, synthetic dyers and power looms introduced from the West after the Meiji Restoration revitalised traditional weaving industry to produce figured fabrics (Hashino and Otsuka 2013b, 2013a; Nakabayashi 2017c).

In the aggregate, the productivity gap of the secondary and tertiary sectors among prefectures rose in the 1890s, but fell in the 1900s. Modern techniques rapidly spread to rural prefectures and improved the productivity of both the traditional and new industries (Fukao et al. 2015: 37–66; Fukao and Settsu 2017).

Such a buoyant economy of rural prefectures would not have been possible without regionally balanced growth under the decentralised regime before the Meiji Restoration. At the same time, as Ma (2004) and Dong, Gong, Peng and Zhao (2015) demonstrate, Japan’s ascendancy in its leading manufacturing industries of silk and cotton was heavily indebted to the transfer of technology from the West. Qing China had been competitive in the traditional silk and cotton industries. However, Japan’s slightly earlier adoption of modern technologies in the late 19th century after the Meiji Restoration drastically enlarged the divergence between Japan and China. Fukao and Settsu (2017) attribute 1.47% of the 1.75% annual growth in labour productivity between 1885 and 1899 to the rise in total factor productivity. The contribution of an increase in capital intensity is estimated at 0.29% of 1.75%. Factors other than capital intensity, such as technology transfer, human capital investment by compulsory schooling, and factor markets liberalisation after the Meiji Restoration, dominated labour productivity improvement in the early phase of Japan’s industrialisation. This achievement, in turn, indicates the cost imposed by the shogunate regime on early modern Japan’s potential. Our upward revision of early modern performance does not reduce the significance of structural reforms after the Meiji Restoration.

References

Aoki
,
Masahiko
,
Jiahua
Che
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.  
2016
.
‘A Three-Party Game of Institutional Resilience Versus Transition: A Model and Comparative History of China-Japan Revisited’.
March,
mimeo
. Available at https://econ.hkbu.edu.hk/eng/Doc/ACN-new-6.pdf

Araki
,
Moriaki
.
1986
[1959].
Bakuhan Taisei Shakai no Seiritsu to Kōzō (Establishment and Structure of the Shogunate Regime)
, 4th ed.
Tokyo
:
Yuhikaku
.

Arimoto
,
Yutaka
.
2005
.
‘State-Contingent Rent Reduction and Tenancy Contract Choice’
.
Journal of Development Economics
76
(
2
):
355
375
.

Arimoto
,
Yutaka
,
Tetsuji
Okazaki
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.  
2010
.
‘Agrarian Land Tenancy in Prewar Japan: Contract Choice and Implications on Productivity’
,
The Developing Economies
48
(
3
):
293
318
.

Bassino
,
Jean-Pascal
, et al.  
2019
.
‘Japan and the Great Divergence, 730–1874’
,
Explorations in Economic History
72
:
1
22
.

Broadberry
,
Stephen
and
Kyoji
Fukao
.  
Forthcoming
.
‘Introduction to Volume 1’.
In
The Cambridge Economic History of Modern World, Volume 1
, eds.
Stephen
Broadberry
and
Kyoji
Fukao
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.

Brown
,
Philip C
.
1993
.
Central Authority and Local Autonomy in the Formation of Early Modern Japan
.
Stanford, CA
:
Stanford University Press
.

——.

2011
.
Cultivating Commons: Joint Ownership of Arable Land in Early Modern Japan
.
Honolulu, HI
:
University of Hawai’i Press
.

——.

2018
.
‘Property Rights That “Work” in the Face of Disaster: Per Share Joint Ownership of Arable in Early Modern and Modern Japan’
.
Global Environment
11
(
2
):
258
293
.

Comín Comín
,
Francis
and
Bartolomée
Yun-Casalilla
.  
2012
.
‘Spain: From Composite Monarchy to Nation-State, 1492–1914. An Exceptional Case?’.
In
The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914,
eds.
Bartolomé
Yun-Casalilla
and
Patrick K
O’Brien
with
Francisco
Comín Comín
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
:
39
66
.

Cox
,
Gary W
and
Mark
Dincecco
.  
Forthcoming
.
‘The Budgetary Origins of Fiscal-Military Prowess’
.
Journal of Politics.
Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3162629 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3162629.

Daunton
,
Martin
.
2012
.
‘The Politics of British taxation, From the Glorious Revolution to the Great War’.
In
The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914
, eds.
Bartolomé
Yun-Casalilla
and
Patrick K.
O’Brien
with
Francisco
Comín Comín
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
,
111
142
.

Deng
,
Kent G
.
2012
.
‘The Continuation and Efficiency of the Chinese Fiscal State, 700 BC–AD 1911’.
In
The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914
, eds.
Bartolomé
Yun-Casalilla
and
Patrick K
O’Brien
with Francisco Comín Comín.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
,
335
352
.

Dincecco
,
Mark
.
2009
.
‘Fiscal Centralization, Limited Government, and Public Revenues in Europe, 1650–1913’
.
The Journal of Economic History
69
(
1
),
48
103
.

——.

2011
.
Political Transformations and Public Finances: Europe, 1650–1913
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.

Dincecco
,
Mark
and
Gabriel
Katz
.  
2014
.
‘State Capacity and Long-Run Economic Performance’
.
The Economic Journal
126
:
189
218
.

Dincecco
,
Mark
and
Massimiliano Gaetano
Onorato
.  
2016
.
‘Military Conflict and the Rise of Urban Europe’
.
Journal of Economic Growth
21
:
259
282
.

Dincecco
,
Mark
and
Mauricio
Prado
.  
2012
.
‘Warfare, Fiscal Capacity, And Performance’
.
Journal of Economic Growth
17
:
171
203
.

Dong
,
Baomin
, et al.  
2015
.
‘Little Divergence: Evidence From Cotton Textiles in Japan and China 1868–1930’
.
Review of Development Economics
19
(
4
):
776
796
.

Farris
,
William Wayne
.
2006
.
Japan’s Medieval Population: Famine, Fertility, and Warfare in a Transformative Age
.
Honolulu, HI
:
University of Hawai’i Press.

——.

2009
.
Daily Life and Demographics in Ancient Japan.
Ann Arbor, MI
:
Center for Japanese Studies, University of Michigan
.

Ferejohn
,
John A
and
Frances McCall
Rosenbluth
.  
2010
.
‘War and State Building in Medieval Japan’.
In
War and State Building in Medieval Japan
, eds.
John A
Ferejohn
and
Frances McCall
Rosenbluth.
Stanford, CA
:
Stanford University Press
:
1
20
.

Francks
,
Penelope
.
2006
.
Rural Economic Development in Japan: From the Nineteenth Century to the Pacific War
.
London
:
Routledge
.

Friday
,
Karl
.
2010
.
‘They Were Soldiers Once: The Early Samurai and the Imperial Court’.
In
War and State Building in Medieval Japan
, eds.
John A
Ferejohn
and
Frances McCall
Rosenbluth
.
Stanford
:
Stanford University Press
:
21
52
.

Fujiki
,
Hisashi
.
2005
.
Katana gari: Buki wo fuin shita minshu (Sword Hunt: Arms Sealed Up by Common People),
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
.

Fukao
,
Kyoji
, et al.  
2015
.
Regional Inequality and Industrial Structure in Japan: 1874–2008.
Tokyo
:
Maruzen Publishing
.

Fukao
,
Kyoji
, et al.  
2017a
.
‘Seisan, bukka, Shotoku no suitei (Estimates of Output, Prices, and Income)’.
In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 2 kan kinsei: 16 seiki matsu kara 19 seiki zenhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 2, The Early Modern Period: From the End of the Sixteenth Century to the First Half of the Nineteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
283
300
.

——.

2017b
.
‘Seisan, bukka, shotoku no suitei (Estimates of Output, Prices, and Income)’.
In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
289
294
.

Fukao
,
Kyoji
and
Tokihiko
Settsu
.  
2017
.
‘Seichō to makuro keizai’ (Growth and the Macro Economy)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 3 kan kindai 1: 19 seiki kōhan kara dai ichiji sekai taisen mae (1913) (Iwanami Lecture Series on the History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 3, The Modern Period 1: From the Late Nineteenth Century to the Eve of the First World War (1913))
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
2
22, 56–59
.

Furushima
,
Toshio
.
1958
.
‘Chiso Kaisei go no jinushiteki tochi shoyū no kakudai to nōgyō rippō (Expansion of Landlordism and the Land Policy After the Land Tax Reform of 1873)’.
In
Nihon Jinushisei Shi Kenkyu (Study on the history of the Japanese Landlord System)
, ed.
Toshio
Furushima
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
315
357
.

Gutmann
,
Jerg
and
Stefan
Voigt
.  
2020
.
‘Traditional Law in Times of the Nation State: Why is it so Prevalent?’
.
Journal of Institutional Economics
16
(
4
):
445
461
.

Hall
,
John Whitney
.
1961
.
‘Foundations of the Modern Japanese Daimyo’
.
The Journal of Asian Studies
20
(
3
):
317
329
.

——.

1981
.
‘Hideyoshi’s Domestic Policies’.
In
Japan before Tokugawa: Political consolidation and economic growth, 1500 to 1650
, eds.
John
Whitney Hall
,
Nagahara
Keiji
and
Kozo
Yamamura
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
:
194
223
.

Hart
,
Oliver D
.
1988
.
‘Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of the Firm’
.
Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization
4
(
1
):
119
140
.

Hashino
,
Tomoko
and
Keijiro
Otsuka
.  
2013a
.
‘Cluster-Based Industrial Development in Contemporary Developing Countries and Modern Japanese Economic History’
.
Journal of the Japanese and International Economies
30
:
19
32
.

——.

2013b
.
‘Hand Looms, Power Looms, and Changing Production Organizations: The Case of the Kiryū Weaving District in Early Twentieth-Century Japan’
.
The Economic History Review
66
(
3
):
785
804
.

Hegel
,
Georg Wilhelm Friedrich
.
1986
.
Grundlinien der Philosophie des Rechts, oder, Naturrecht und Staatswissenschaft im Grundrisse: Mit Hegels eigenhandigen Notizen und den mundlichen Zusatzen
. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.

Honda
,
Hiroyuki
.
2017
.
‘Chūsei kahei: Traisen no jidai (Medieval Currency: Era of Imported Coins)’.
In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
92
116
.

Ike
,
Susumu
.
2010
.
‘Competence Over Loyalty: Lords and Retainers in Medieval Japan’
. In
War and State Building in Medieval Japan
, eds.
John A
Ferejohn
and
Frances
McCall Rosenbluth
.
Stanford, CA
:
Stanford University Press
:
53
70
.

Imamura
,
Naoki
and
Masaki
Nakabayashi.
 
2017
.
‘Joshō dai 3 setsu shotoku no bunpai’ (Introduction: Section 3. Distribution of Income)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 2 kan kinsei: 16 seiki matsu kara 19 seiki zenhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, volume 2, The Early Modern Period: From the End of the Sixteenth Century to the Early Nineteenth Century),
eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
33
49, 55–60
.

Inaba
,
Tsuguharu
.
2010
.
‘Community Vitality in Medieval Japan’.
In
War and State Building in Medieval Japan
, eds.
John A
Ferejohn
and
Frances McCall
Rosenbluth
.
Stanford, CA
:
Stanford University Press
:
91
109
.

Isogai
,
Fujio
.
2008
.
‘Chōshō/Hōen no kikin to fujiwara atsumitsu kanjin ni tsuite (A Report by Fujiwara Atumitu on the Issue to the Chousyou Houen famine A.D.1135)’
.
Bulletin of Daito Bunka University
46
:
177
197
.

Iwahashi
,
Masaru
.
1999
.
‘The Institutional Framework’.
In
The Economic History of Japan, 1600–1990, Volume 1: Emergence of Economic Society in Japan, 1600–1859
, eds.
Akira
Hayami
,
Osamu
Saitō
, and
Ronald P
Toby
.
New York
:
Oxford University Press
,
85
104
.

Koyama
,
Mark
,
Chiaki
Moriguchi
, and
Tuan-Hwee
Sng
.  
2018
.
‘Geopolitics and Asia’s Little Divergence: State Building in China and Japan After 1850’
.
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
155
:
178
204
.

Kumon
,
Yuzuru
.
2020
.
‘The Labor Intensive Path: Wages, Incomes and the Work Year in Japan, 1610-1932’
, Graduate School of Economics, the University of Tokyo, Discussion Paper Series CIRJE-F-1154. Available at http://www.cirje.e.u-tokyo.ac.jp/research/dp/2020/2020cf1154.pdf

Kwon
,
Grace
.
2002
.
State Formation, Property Relations, and the Development of Tokugawa Economy (1600–1868)
.
New York
:
Routledge
.

Ma
,
Debin
.
2004
.
‘Why Japan, not China, was the First to Develop in East Asia: Lessons From Sericulture, 1850–1937’
.
Economic Development and Cultural Change
52
(
2
):
369
394
.

Makihara
,
Shigeyuki
.
2017
.
‘Nōson kinyū/chihō toshi kinyū’ (Finance in Rural Villages and Local Cities)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 2 kan kinsei: 16 seiki matsu kara 19 seiki zenhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 2, The Early Modern Period: From the End of the Sixteenth Century to the First Half of the Nineteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
,
112
130, 145–146
.

Malanima
,
Paolo
.
2005
.
‘Urbanisation and the Italian Economy During the Last Millennium’
.
European Review of Economic History
9
(
1
):
97
122
.

——.

2010
.
‘The Long Decline of a Leading Economy: GDP in Central and Northern Italy, 1300–1913’
.
European Review of Economic History
15
(
2
):
169
219
.

Malinowski
,
Miko Laj
and
Jan Luiten
van Zanden
.  
2017
.
‘Income and its Distribution in Preindustrial Poland’
.
Cliometrica
11
(
3
):
375
404
.

Mandai
,
Yu
.
2019
.
Kinsei kinai no gono keiei to hansei (Wealthy Farmers and Domain Administration in the Early Modern Kinai Region)
.
Tokyo
:
Hanawa Shobo
.

Mandai
,
Yu
and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.  
2017
.
‘Dai 3 shō dai 1 setsu: Kinsei no tochi hōsei to jinushi keiei’ (Chapter 3: Section 1. The Land Law and Landlordism in Early Modern Times)’.
In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 2 kan kinsei: 16 seiki matsu kara 19 seiki zenhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 2, The Early Modern Period: From the End of the Sixteenth Century to the First Half of the Nineteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
150
176
.

Mandai
,
Yu
and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.  
2018
.
‘Stabilize the Peasant Economy: Governance of Foreclosure by the Shogunate’
.
Journal of Policy Modeling
40
(
2
):
305
327
.

Marx
,
K
.
1986
.
‘Okonomisch-philosophische Manuskripte aus dem Jahre 1844’
. In
Karl Marx Friedrich Engels Werke Band 40
, ed. Institute fur Marxismus-Leninismus beim zk der SED. Berlin: Dietz Verlag: 111–207,
673
676
.

Midorikawa
,
Kazuo
.
2016
.
‘Inatasokuryō no minaoshi ni yoru kodai no suidenseisanryoku kitei to sozeichōshū masu no saikentō’ (A Re-Examination of the Official Standards on Crop Yields of Paddy Fields: A Consideration of Inasoku in the Heian Period)
.
Shakai-Keizaishigaku (Socio-Economic History)
82
(
1
):
27
49
.

——.

2019
.
‘Nihon kodai chusei no suiden seisanryoku (Estimating the Productivity of Paddy Fields in Ancient and Medieval Japan)’
.
Shakai-Keizai Shigaku (Socio-Economic History)
85
(
2
):
3
24
.

Mitani
,
Hiroshi
.
2020
.
‘Japan’s Meiji Revolution in Global History: Searching for Some Generalizations Out of History’
.
Asian Review of World Histories
8
(
1
):
41
57
.

Miyamoto
,
Matao
.
1999
.
‘Quantitative Aspects of Tokugawa Economy’.
In
The Economic History of Japan, 1600–1990, Volume 1: Emergence of Economic Society in Japan, 1600–1859
, eds.
Akira
Hayami
,
Osamu
Saito
, and
Ronald P
Toby
.
New York
:
Oxford University Press
:
36
84
.

Nagahara
,
Keiji
.
1973
.
Nihon Chusei Shakai Kozo no Kenkyu (Study on the Social Structure of Medieval Japan)
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
.

——.

1975
.
‘Landownership Under the shōen-kokugaryō System’
.
The Journal of Japanese Studies
1
(
2
):
269
296
.

Nakabayashi
,
Masaki
.
2006
.
‘The Rise of a Factory Industry: Silk Reeling in Suwa, Nagano’.
In
The Role of Traditional Factors in Japanese Industrialization: 1880–1920
, ed.
Masayuki
Tanimoto
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
:
183
216
.

——.

2012
.
‘The Rise of a Japanese Fiscal State’.
In
The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914,
eds.
Bartolomé
Yun-Casalilla
and
Patrick K
O’Brien
with
Francisco Comín
Comín
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
:
327
409
.

——.

2014
. ‘
Imposed Efficiency of Treaty Ports: Japanese Industrialization and Western Imperialist Institutions’
.
Review of Development Economics
18
(
2
):
254
271
.

——.

2017a
.
‘Contained Crisis and Socialized Risk: Unconventional Monetary Policy by the Bank of Japan in the 1890s’
.
Research in International Business and Finance
40
:
231
241
.

——.

2017b
.
‘Shihonshugi teki na seisan soshiki no keisei: Kōgyō (Formation of Capitalist Organizations of Production: Manufacturing)’.
In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 3 kan kindai 1: 19 seiki kōhan kara dai ichiji sekai taisen mae (1913) (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 3, The Modern Period 1: From the Late Nineteenth Century to the Eve of the First World War (1913)), eds. Kyoji Fukao, Naofumi Nakamura, and Masaki Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
192
212
.

——.

2017c
.
‘Honesty, Diligence and Skill: Risk Sharing and Specialization in the Kiryu Silk Weaving Cluster, Japan’
.
Review of Development Economics
21
(
4
):
1401
1424
.

——.

2019a
.
‘Ownership Structure and Market Efficiency: Stockholder/Manager Conflicts at the Dawn of Japanese Capitalism’
.
Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money
61
:
189
212
.

——.

2019b
.
‘From Family Security to the Welfare State: Path Dependency of Social Security on the Difference in Legal Origins’
.
Economic Modelling
82
:
280
293
.

——.

2020
.
‘The Thin Line Between Economic Dynamism and Social Stability: Regulation and Deregulation in Japan (12th to the 19th C.)’
. In
Capitalisms: Towards A Global History
, eds.
Kaveh
Yazdani
and
Dilip
Menon
.
New Delhi, India
:
Oxford University Press
:
277
305
.

——.

Forthcoming
.
‘Tokugawa Japan and the Foundations of Modern Economic Growth in Asia’.
In
The Cambridge Economic History of Modern World, Volume 1
, eds.
Stephen
Broadberry
and
Kyoji
Fukao
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
.

Nakamura
,
Naofumi
.
2000
.
‘Meiji-era Industrialization and Provincial Vitality: The Significance of the First-Enterprise Boom of the 1880s’
.
Social Science Japan Journal
3
(
2
):
187
205
.

——.

2010
.
Chihō kara no sangyō kakumei: Nihon ni okeru kigyō bokkō no gendoryoku (Local Perspectives on Japanese Industrial Revolution: The Driving Force of Japan’s Industrialization)
.
Nagoya
:
Nagoya University Press
.

——.

2014
.
‘Nihon no sangyō kakumei’ (Japan’s Industrial Revolution)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon rekishi dai 16 kan kingendai 2 (Iwanami Lecture Series, Japanese History, Volume 16, The Modern Period 2)
, eds.
Toru
Otsu
,
Eiji
Sakurai
,
Joji
Fujii
,
Yutaka
Yoshida
, and
Sungsi
Lee
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
147
182
.

——.

2015
.
‘Reconsidering the Japanese Industrial Revolution: Local Entrepreneurs in the Cotton Textile Industry During the Meiji Era’
.
Social Science Japan Journal
18
(
1
):
23
44
.

Nishitani
,
Masahiro
.
2006
.
Nihon Chusei no Shoyu Kozo (Ownership Structure in Medieval Japan)
.
Tokyo
:
Hanawa Shobo
.

Nishitani
,
Masahiro
.
2017
.
‘Chūsei no nōgyō kōzō’ (Structure of the Medieval Agriculture)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
148
177
.

Nishitani
,
Masahiro
and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.  
2017
.
‘Joshō dai 3 setsu shotoku bunpai’ (Introduction: Section 3. Distribution of Income)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
33
49
.

Nishitani
,
Masahiro
,
Daisuke
Hayashima
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.  
2017
.
‘Joshō dai 2 setsu seifu no yakuwari’ (Introduction: Section 2. Role of the Administration).
In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
23
33
.

North
,
Douglass C
.
2005
.
Understanding the Process of Economic Change
.
Princeton, NJ
:
Princeton University Press
.

O’Brien
,
Patrick K
and
Philip A
Hunt
.  
1993
.
‘The Rise of a Fiscal State in England, 1485–1815’
.
Historical Research
66
(
160
):
129
176
.

Oishi
,
Hisataka
.
1969
[1794].
Jikata hanreiroku jokan (Records of Local Practices, volume 1) (Written and submitted to the Lord of Takasaki in 1794)
.
Tokyo
:
Kondo Shuppansha
.

Ono
,
Mizuo
.
1996
.
Edo bakufu zaisei shiron (Fiscal History of the Edo Shogunate)
.
Tokyo
:
Yoshikawa Kobunkan
.

Ono
,
Mizuo
, ed.
2008a
.
Edo bakufu zaisei shiryo shusei gekan (Collected Documents on the Fiscal Policy of the Edo Shogunate, volume 2)
.
Tokyo
:
Yoshikawa Kobunkan
.

——.

2008b
.
Edo Bakufu Zaisei Shiryo Shusei Jokan (Collected Documents on the Fiscal Policy of the Edo Shogunate, volume 1)
.
Tokyo
:
Yoshikawa Kobunkan
.

Oyama
,
Kyohei
.
1979
.
Nihon chūsei nōsonshi no kenkyū (Study on the History of Farming Villages in Medieval Japan)
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
.

Palma
,
Nuno
and
Jaime
Reis
.  
2019
.
‘From Convergence to Divergence: Portuguese Economic Growth, 1527–1850’
,
The Journal of Economic History
79
(
2
):
477
506
.

Pamuk
,
Şevket
.
2012
.
‘The Evolution of Fiscal Institutions in the Ottoman Empire, 1500–1914’.
In
The Rise of Fiscal States: A Global History, 1500–1914
, eds.
Bartolomé
Yun-Casalilla
and
Patrick K
O’Brien
with
Francisco
Comín Comín
.
Cambridge
:
Cambridge University Press
:
304
331
.

Piggott
,
Joan R
.
2018
.
‘Estates: Their History and Historiography’.
In
Land, Power, and the Sacred: The Estate System in Medieval Japan,
eds.
Janet R
Goodwin
and
Joan R
Piggott
.
University of Hawai’i Press
:
3
36
.

Ravina
,
Mark
.
1995
.
‘State-Building and Political Economy in Early-Modern Japan’
.
The Journal of Asian Studies
54
(
4
):
997
1022
.

——.

1999
.
Land and Lordship in Early Modern Japan.
Stanford, CA
:
Stanford University Press
.

Saito
,
Osamu
.
1983
.
‘Population and the Peasant Family Economy in Proto-Industrial Japan’
,
Journal of Family History
8
(
1
):
30
54
.

——.

1998
.
‘Two Kinds of Stem-Family System? Traditional Japan and Europe Compared’
,
Continuity and Change
13
(
1
):
167
186
.

——.

2000
.
‘Marriage, Family Labour and the Stem Family Household: Traditional Japan in a Comparative Perspective’
.
Continuity and Change
15
(
1
):
17
45
.

——.

2002
.
‘The Frequency of Famines as Demographic Correctives in the Japanese Past’.
In
Famine Demography: Perspectives from the Past and Present
, eds.
Tim
Dyson
and
Cormac O
Gáda
.
Oxford
:
Oxford University Press
:
218
239
.

——.

2009
.
‘Land, Labour and Market Forces in Tokugawa Japan’
.
Continuity and Change
24
(
1
):
169
196
.

——.

2015a
. ‘
Climate, Famine, and Population in Japanese History: A Long-Term Perspective’.
In
Environment and Society in the Japanese Islands: From Prehistory to the Present
, eds.
Bruce L
Batten
and
Philip C
Brown
.
Corvallis, OR
:
Oregon State University Press
:
213
329
.

——.

2015b
.
Growth and Inequality in the Great and Little Divergence Debate: A Japanese Perspective
.
The Economic History Review
68
(
2
):
399
419
.

——.

2018
. ‘
1600 nen no zenkoku jinkō: 17 seiki jinkō keizaishi saikōchiku no kokoromi’ (Japan’s Population in 1600: An Attempt to Reconstruct the History of the Population and Economy in the Seventeenth Century)
.
Shakai Keizai Shigaku (Socio-Economic History)
84
(
1
):
3
23
.

Saito
,
Osamu
and
Masanori
Takashima
.  
2016
.
‘Estimating the Shares of Secondary- and Tertiary Sector Outputs in the Age of Early Modern Growth: The Case of Japan, 1600–18741’
.
European Review of Economic History
20
(
3
):
368
386
.

——.

2017a
.
‘Jinko to toshika to shugyo kozo’ (Population, Urbanization and Employment Structure)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century), eds. Kyoji Fukao, Naofumi Nakamura, and Masaki Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
57
89
.

——.

2017b
.
‘Jinkō to toshika, idō to shūgyō’ (Population and urbanization, movement and employment)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 2 kan kinsei: 16 seiki matsu kara 19 seiki zenhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 2, The Early Modern Period: From the End of the Sixteenth Century to the First Half of the Nineteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
62
104
.

——.

2020
.
‘Chūsei kōki no jisshitsu chingin: Hendō to kakusa’ (Real Wages in late Medieval Japan: Changes and Differentials),
Keizai Kenkyu (The Economic Review)
71
(
2
):
129
143
.

Sakane
,
Yoshihiro
.
2014
.
‘Jinushisei no seiritsu to nōson shakai’ (Emergence of Landlordism and Rural Society)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon rekishi dai 16 kan kingendai 2 (Iwanami Lecture Series, Japanese History, Volume 16, The Modern Period 2)
, eds.
Toru
Otsu
,
Eiji
Sakurai
,
Joji
Fujii
,
Yutaka
Yoshida
, and
Sungsi
Lee
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
215
248
.

——.

2019
.
‘Nihon dentō shakai kara mita kindai nihon no keizai hatten’ (A Viewpoint from the Japanese Traditional Society on Japan’s Economic Development)
. In
Nihon no Keizai Hatten wo Dou Toraeruka (A Way of Understanding Japan’s Economic Development)
, eds.
Yoshihiro
Sakane
and
Yoshitsugu
Mori
.
Osaka
:
Seibundo Shuppansha
:
65
95
.

Sakane
,
Yoshihiro
and
Yutaka
Arimoto
.  
2017
.
‘Kōgyōka ki no nihon nōgyō’ (Japanese Agriculture Under Industrialization)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 3 kan kindai 1: 19 seiki kōhan kara dai ichiji sekai taisen mae (1913) (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 3, The Modern Period 1: From the Late Nineteenth Century to the Eve of the First World War (1913))
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
152
178, 187–189
.

Sakurai
,
Eiji
.
2008
.
‘Currency and Credit in Medieval Japan’
.
International Journal of Asian Studies
5
(
1
):
53
70
.

——.

2018
.
Medieval Japan’s Commercial Economy and the Estate System’.
In
Land, Power, and the Sacred: The Estate System in Medieval Japan
, eds.
Janet R
Goodwin
and
Joan R
Piggott
.
University of Hawai’i Press
:
37
58
.

Schreurs
,
Gerardus Joseph
.
2019
.
‘Government Institutions and Economic Development in Tokugawa Japan: A Tale of Systems Competition’.
Doctoral thesis submitted to Hitotsubashi University, available at doi:10.15057/30297.

Segal
,
Ethan Isaac
.
2011
.
Coins, Trade, and the State: Economic Growth in Early Medieval Japan.
Cambridge, MA
:
Harvard University Asia Center
.

Smith
,
Adam
.
1937
[1776].
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
.
New York
:
Modern Library
.

Sng
,
Tuan-Hwee
and
Chiaki
Moriguchi
.  
2014
.
‘Asia’s Little Divergence: State Capacity in China and Japan Before 1850’
.
Journal of Economic Growth
19
:
439
470
.

Suzuki
,
Atsuko
.
2017
.
‘Chusei no shosangyo’ (Industries in Medieval Times)
. In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
,
235
258
.

Takahashi
,
Noriyuki
.
2008
.
Kamakura Bakufu Gunsei to Gokeninsei (Military Command of The Kamakura Shogunate and the Vassal Relationship)
.
Tokyo
:
Yoshikawa Kobunkan
.

Takashima
,
Masanori
.
2017
.
Keizai seicho no nihonshi (Economic Growth in the Japanese Past)
.
Nagoya
:
Nagoya University Press.

Takatsuki
,
Yasuo
.
2012
.
Kinsei kome shijo no keisei to tenkai: Bakufu shiho to dojima kome kaisho no hatten (Creation of the Early Modern Rice Market: The Shogunate Judiciary and Development of the Dojima Rice Exchange)
.
Nagoya
:
Nagoya University Press
.

Vries
,
Peer
.
2020
.
Averting a Great Divergence: State and Economy in Japan, 1868–1937
.
London
:
Bloomsbury
.

Wakita
,
Haruko
.
1975
.
‘Towards a wider perspective on medieval commerce’
.
The Journal of Japanese Studies
1
(
2
):
321
345
.

Watanuki
,
Tomoko
.
2017
.
‘Chūsei no kōeki’ (Trades in Medieval Times).
In
Iwanami kōza nihon keizai no rekishi dai 1 kan chūsei: 11 seiki kara 16 seiki kōhan (Iwanami Lecture Series, History of the Japanese Economy, Volume 1, The Medieval Period: From the Eleventh Century to the Second Half of the Sixteenth Century)
, eds.
Kyoji
Fukao
,
Naofumi
Nakamura
, and
Masaki
Nakabayashi
.
Tokyo
:
Iwanami Shoten
:
259
294
.

White
,
James W
.
1995
.
Ikki: Social Conflict and Political Protest in Early Modern Japan.
Ithaca, NY
:
Cornell University Press
.

The authors are thankful for insightful suggestions from two anonymous referees and thank Editor-in-Chief Gregory W. Noble, Managing Editor Meredith Shaw, and Special Issue Editor Susumu Cato for their helpful advice. They also appreciate discussions with Gabriel Alejandro Facchini Palma, Rok Spruk, Hyunjoo Yang, and Anthony Rossiter during the recording process and Q & A time of our session at the Econometric Society Virtual World Congress 2020. This work was supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science KAKENHI Grant Numbers JP18H03630, 16H06322, 19K13755, and the JAPAN CENTER FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH.

Footnotes

1

http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/oriindex.htm/, last accessed on 29 August 2019.

2

Kunitachi, Tokyo, Japan. http://www.ier.hit-u.ac.jp/histatdb, last accessed on 29 August 2019.

3

Ono (1996: 441–448). The original document for 1651–1715 is ‘Okouchi ke kiroku’ (Records of the Okouchi family), Ono, ed (2008b: 106–130), and that for 1716–1841 is ‘Mukoyama Seisai zakki oyobi zattetsu’ (Memoranda and notes by Seisai Mukoyama), Ono, ed (2008a: 62–80).

4

See Oishi (1969[1794]: 73); the author, Hisataka Oishi, was a county governor of the Takasaki Domain in the 18th century.

This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted reuse, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.