-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Bart M. Lambrecht, Grzegorz Pawlina, João C. A. Teixeira, Making, Buying, and Concurrent Sourcing: Implications for Operating Leverage and Stock Beta , Review of Finance, Volume 20, Issue 3, May 2016, Pages 1013–1043, https://doi.org/10.1093/rof/rfv027
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
We present a real options model of a firm’s make-or-buy decision under demand uncertainty. “Making” is subject to decreasing returns to scale, fixed costs, and capital investment. “Buying” happens at a fixed price and requires no investment. Three distinct procurement regimes endogenously arise: buying, making, or concurrent sourcing for, respectively, low, intermediate, and high demand. Capital constraints encourage buying or concurrent sourcing. Operating leverage peaks when the firm switches between buying and making, and it is lowest (and negative) at the switch between making and concurrent sourcing. This non-monotonic pattern mirrors and drives the behavior of the firm’s beta.
1. Introduction
Whether to make or to buy a product is for many firms an important decision. Empirical studies (see Harrigan, 1986 ; Dutta et al., 1995 ; Parmigiani, 2007 ; among others) have shown that some firms rely exclusively on internal production, others procure the good exclusively through external suppliers, while yet others simultaneously rely on internal production and outsourcing. The last category is particularly puzzling as a firm that both makes and buys the same good incurs the costs that are associated with both outsourcing and internal production. Furthermore, concurrent sourcing appears to be widespread. 1
1 Heriot and Kulkarni (2001) , Heide (2003) , and Parmigiani (2007) find that, respectively, 57%, 31%, and 28% of the firms in their sample rely on concurrent sourcing. Empirical observations have also shown that many local governments both make and buy the same service ( Warner and Hefetz, 2008 ).
There is also empirical evidence that aggregate outsourcing activity within an economy is not constant over time, but occurs in waves and that these waves are linked to the state of the economy. 2
2 Although outsourcing has been used for more than a century, the first wave of outsourcing started in the 1970s and 1980s in the manufacturing sector. The reader is referred to Domberger (1999) for further details on past outsourcing activity.
This article develops a real options model that explains some of the observed behavior and addresses some unanswered questions. Using analytical solutions, we examine how operating flexibility affects a firm’s operating leverage, its beta and expected returns. The five novel features of our article are as follows. First, we model internal production as a more capital intensive procurement mode than buying. The existing literature, which is largely static in nature, has ignored the role of capital investment because there is no essential difference between fixed operating costs and sunk investment costs in a static model without a time dimension or without meaningful variation in the production policy. However, in a dynamic, uncertain environment where firms may switch production mode or face excess capacity, both types of costs are very different in nature. For example, by switching from making to buying, a firm may be able to cut its fixed production costs but not its sunk investments.
Second, in our setting firms have the flexibility to engage in concurrent sourcing. This generates a number of new insights compared with the existing literature which traditionally assumes that firms can either outsource or produce in-house, but not both at the same time.
Third, our article characterizes analytically how demand shocks affect the firm’s optimal operating mode. We show how firms, in response to economic shocks, switch back and forth between outsourcing, internal production, and concurrent sourcing, and analyze how this affects operating leverage. We show that concurrent sourcing is not a weighted average of the make and buy strategies. Instead it is a distinctly different strategy that is situated to the right of the buy and makes strategies along the firm’s output spectrum. Our theoretical model supports recent empirical work by Parmigiani (2007) who explores whether concurrent sourcing should be interpreted as lying somewhere on a continuous make-buy spectrum, reflecting a partial degree of integration as implicit in the transaction cost theories, or whether it should be considered as a third, distinct strategy. She finds strong support for the latter hypothesis. It appears that firms first decide whether or not to produce internally, and only subsequently determine the percentage of good that is internally produced.
Fourth, we analyze the effect of capital constraints and irreversible investment. Often firms may not be able to invest the optimal amount due to capital constraints. We therefore examine how the optimal output level and operating regime vary with the severity of the capital constraint.
Finally, we derive testable implications regarding the effect of the firm’s procurement flexibility on its expected returns. We show that the firm’s beta is closely linked to the degree of operating leverage (see also Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004) , who introduced the operating leverage hypothesis). Beta is also determined by a complex interplay between the returns to scale associated with each operating regime and the economies of scale associated with internal production.
We now briefly sketch our real options model and its main results. We consider a firm that produces output for which demand is stochastic and determined by an iso-elastic inverse demand function. The output can be made internally, or it can be bought at an exogenously given fixed unit price. 3
3 In Appendix C, we consider the case where the outsourcing price depends on the quantity ordered.
Three distinct procurement regimes endogenously arise. For low demand levels, the firm purchases all required quantity of the good (i.e., buying ). For intermediate demand, the firm produces all units in-house (i.e., making ). Finally, for high demand, the firm produces a fixed threshold quantity internally and outsources any quantity in excess of the threshold (i.e., concurrent sourcing ). In such a case, outsourcing is used as an “overflow” facility to deal with excess demand. Importantly, with decreasing returns to scale concurrent sourcing survives even if the firm can make internal capital (dis)investments in a frictionless manner.
We show that a tighter capital constraint encourages buying or concurrent sourcing. The availability of cheap outsourcing imposes a minimum capital requirement on firms. Firms that cannot operate at a sufficiently large-scale stop producing internally, irrespective of the state of the economy. The cheaper it is to buy, the larger the scale required for internal production. This may explain why the arrival of cheap overseas outsourcing led to the closure of many small labor intensive production units.
Our analysis provides new insights into the behavior of operating leverage when firms can switch between different operating modes. 4
4 The measure used for operating leverage in this article is
The behavior of the stock beta mirrors our measure of operating leverage. However (unlike operating leverage), beta is a smooth function of the state variable as beta is based on the sensitivity of the firm’s value (which is based on future expectations). Beta is low under buying, and gradually reaches a peak as the firm moves toward making. Under making beta gradually declines as operating leverage decreases. As diseconomies of scale set in (i.e., the marginal cost exceeds the average cost), beta moves toward a minimum, but then gradually increases again as the firm starts engaging in concurrent sourcing. Since beta peaks around the buying-to-making switching point, and reaches a minimum in the neighborhood of the making-to-concurrent sourcing switching point, it follows that the beta exhibits a characteristic non-monotonic pattern.
Our work and research methods are related to the real options literature that studies a firm’s optimal capacity choice under uncertainty and irreversibility. Key papers on this topic are Abel ( 1983 , 1984 ), Pindyck (1988) , Triantis and Hodder (1990) , He and Pindyck (1992) , and Kandel and Pearson (2002) . Triantis and Hodder (1990) value flexible production systems with multiple products, whereas we consider a firm with multiple operating modes all generating the same product. Kandel and Pearson (2002) analyze the optimal investment and production decision of a firm facing stochastic demand with access to two alternative production technologies. Our article differs in two important respects. First, by including a more general cost function (based on the Cobb–Douglas production technology), we are able to rationalize the choice of the reversible technology (buying) and a combination of both technologies (concurrent sourcing). Second, by focusing on either completely irreversible investment or perfectly reversible investment, we are able to generate insightful closed form solutions and a rich set of comparative statics results regarding the timing and size of investment, the value of the option to invest, the firm’s operating leverage and its systematic risk (beta).
Several papers on investment in costly capacity ( Baldursson, 1998 ; Grenadier, 2002 ; Aguerrevere, 2003 , 2009 ) have focused on capacity as a strategic variable when firms are competing with other firms. None of these papers captures the make-or-buy decision because they allow for one production method only.
Our paper is also related to a growing literature pioneered by Berk, Green, and Naik (1999) that links corporate decisions to asset returns. In Berk, Green, and Naik (1999) , firms that perform well tend to be those that discovered valuable investment opportunities. Good news is associated on average with lower systematic risk. Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004) introduce operating leverage in the real options framework and demonstrate that a book-to-market effect can be directly related to fixed operating costs. Zhang (2005) presents an industry equilibrium model of asymmetric convex adjustment costs of investment in which value firms have more difficulty severing their capital stocks than growth firms. Cooper (2006) analyzes the effects of nonconvex adjustment costs, irreversibility of investment, and operating leverage on the behavior of financial asset prices. Novy-Marx (2011) derives and tests implications of the operating leverage hypothesis and documents that operating leverage predicts returns in the cross-section. 5
5 More recently, the focus has shifted to examining the relation between stock returns and financing decisions (see Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2006 , 2010 ), Whited and Wu (2006) , Lyandres, Sun, and Zhang (2008) , Li, Livdan, and Zhang (2009) , Livdan, Sapriza, and Zhang (2009) , Gomes and Schmid (2010) and Ozdagli (2012) , among others.
6 Studies focusing on financial leverage tend to come to the same conclusion (see Li, Livdan, and Zhang, 2009; Ozdagli, 2012, among others).
7 Our article is also related to the literature on outsourcing and vertical integration (see Joskow (2005) for a comprehensive review). Only a few theoretical papers consider the possibility of concurrent sourcing (see, e.g., Carlton, 1979 ; Rob and Vettas, 2003 ; Alvarez and Stenbacka, 2007 ; Allon and Van Mieghem, 2010 ) and typically focus on the trade-off between cost and responsiveness.
The remainder of the article is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the basic assumptions of the model and analyzes the optimal procurement decision for a fixed level of capital. Section 3 studies the optimal procurement decision with fully reversible capital. Section 4 examines how output price uncertainty and the outsourcing price affect optimal investment, production, and the company beta. Section 5 discusses the model’s empirical implications. Section 6 concludes.
2. Optimal Production with a Fixed Level of Capital
A firm sells a product that can either be produced in-house (making) or can be bought from an external supplier (buying). The firm can also produce some units internally and buy the remainder (concurrent sourcing). The firm faces an isoelastic inverse demand function which is given by
8 Goods that are bought (or produced internally) cannot be sold back to the upstream suppliers. The market structure adopted is similar to monopolistic competition. Each firm has monopoly power (by virtue of its brand differentiation or location, for example) while at the same time there are a sufficient amount of suppliers of the product in its generic form for the purchase price p to be constant. The market structure may particularly apply to industries such as cereals, toothpaste, clothing, orcatering and services in large cities. In Appendix C, we consider an extension in which a larger order attracts a bigger discount and
9 Our results are robust to alternative specifications for the demand and cost functions. A previous version of the article that combined a linear demand function with a quadratic cost function generated results that are qualitatively very similar.
10 If outsourcing price were to decrease with quantity bought (cf. footnote D), the necessary condition for concurrent sourcing to occur becomes
If
buying (regime 1) is optimal for
,making (regime 2) is optimal for
,concurrent sourcing (regime 3) is optimal for
.

Proposition 1 conveys a number of important insights about the economics of outsourcing and internal production. A key determinant in the make-or-buy decision is the price p at which the product can be bought versus the cost at which it can be produced. This comparison is reflected in the condition
11 This may explain why large firms, such as Nike or Apple, do none of their manufacturing despite having huge volumes.
The condition for internal production to be optimal for some demand levels (i.e.,

Optimal procurement regime for a given level of installed capital, K , and the demand parameter α for the following set of parameter values: A = 0.2,
Another important determinant in the make-or-buy decision is the output price captured by the demand parameter α . The price at which the firm can sell the finished production determines the marginal revenue and therefore the optimal output level. The optimal output level is (globally) increasing in α , creating a link between α and the optimal production regime: buying, making, and concurrent sourcing are optimal for low, intermediate, and high demand levels, respectively.
The results lend support to the notion of an optimal production range. The firm can only efficiently produce internally for output levels in the range
Proposition 1 is illustrated in Figure 1 for the base set of parameter values A = 0.2,
While internal production always becomes optimal for a sufficiently high demand level if the firm cannot outsource (the firm will hire more labor to make up for the lack of capital), this is no longer the case when firms have access to cheap outsourcing. The availability of outsourcing imposes a minimum capital requirement on firms: firms that cannot operate at a sufficiently large scale stop producing internally, irrespective of the state of the economy. The cheaper it is to buy, the larger the scale required for internal production (i.e.,
3. Optimal Production with Fully Reversible Capital
12 If a larger order attracted a bigger discount, so
The optimal procurement regimes, profit , and output levels with fully reversible capital are as given in Proposition 1 but with ξ and c replaced by
It follows that the firm’s production and procurement decisions are qualitatively the same under the irreversible and reversible investment scenarios. One merely has to replace the parameters ξ and c by
13 They are no longer a function of capital K , which is chosen endogenously in this case.
4. Optimal Production and Capital Investment with Demand Uncertainty
14 This restriction is due to the fact that variable cash flows are proportional to powers
We assume that capital does not depreciate. Investment in capital is irreversible and, once chosen, the level of capital cannot be changed. The firm can, however, change the procurement regime in response to economic shocks. Changes in the procurement regime are fully reversible (there are no switching costs).
Introducing a dynamic framework separates the investment decision and production decision and requires that the problem be solved in two stages: (1) installing the optimal capital level, K , at the optimal investment threshold
As is standard with dynamic optimization, we solve the problem backwards. We first solve for the optimal production level and procurement regime taking the firm’s investment K as given. This problem corresponds to the one described in Section 2 (for a given level of K ) with the parameter α changing randomly over time according to process (14). 15
15 The dynamics therefore corresponds to vertical fluctuations in the
We are primarily interested in the effect of demand uncertainty ( σ ) and the outsourcing price ( p ) on the optimal investment level K , the optimal investment threshold
We start off by deriving the value of a mature firm, that is, after the capital investment K is made. Subsequently, we calculate the value of a young firm that currently purchases the entire required quantity of the good and has a single option to invest.
4.1 The Value of a Mature Firm
Once the investment K has been made, the value of a mature firm can be obtained by noting that all the flexibility arises from the reversibility regarding the procurement decision. As there is no cost associated with regime changes, the procurement regime and the optimal output level are selected to maximize the instantaneous profit flow and, therefore, are determined by the cutoff values and the output levels established earlier in the paper. In particular, critical level of α that separates the make and buy regimes is given by
16 The dependence of constants A i and B i on K has been omitted for the brevity of notation. Moreover, B1 ( A3 ) equals zero as there is no flexibility associated with a downward (an upward) movement of the state variable α under buying (concurrent sourcing).
17 Obviously, the value of only those components that correspond to procurement regimes in which capacity is utilized (PV 2 and PV 3 ) depends on the amount of installed capacity K . In addition, the present value of the incremental profit flow resulting from the output made under concurrent sourcing, which we denote by
Having obtained the expression for
It is meaningful to analyze the relation between q A and the state of the economy, measured by the level of α , for the reversible case (as otherwise capital stock is fixed). Optimal capital stock is zero under buying, constant under concurrent sourcing, and an increasing function of α under making. Upon substituting
18 If options to switch regimes and fixed costs were to be ignored, average q would be constant under making.
Note that an increase in qA associated with an improving state of the economy is not always associated with a corresponding increase in investment in capital. In fact,
19 If making was the only option,
4.2 The Value of a Young Firm and the Optimal Capital Investment
The value of the option to invest (OV), the value of the installed investment net of the investment cost, and the optimal investment threshold (

The option value,
4.3 The Effect of Uncertainty and Outsourcing Price
In this section we explore how uncertainty ( σ ) and outsourcing price ( p ) affect the timing of irreversible investment, the size of the investment, and the value of the option to invest. Since the procurement regime is fully reversible, irreversibility only applies to capital investment. Analytical expressions for the comparative statics with respect to σ and p are not available. Therefore, we rely on a numerical analysis with its results depicted in Figure 3 (parameter values correspond to the base set, unless stated otherwise).

Investment threshold (panels A and B), option value (panels C and D), and capacity level (panels E and F) for the following set of parameter values:


20
21 The option value asymptotes to a bounded value as




The results in panels E and F show that higher outsourcing price reduces the amount of capital investment when investment is irreversible as the indirect effect of waiting dominates. Indeed, we know that as
is negative there. Numerical simulations indicate that the result extends for the entire domain of p . The intuition for it is simple: if the outsourcing price is high, investment occurs at a lower level of demand so capital investment is relatively modest. 22
22 In the limiting case of
23 Note that the upper bound for installed capital in the fully reversible case is higher and equals
Finally, consider the effect of uncertainty and the outsourcing price on the optimal regime switching thresholds
The effect of outsourcing price on the regime boundaries is both direct and indirect. For a given K , higher p results in an increased gap between
24 Numerical simulations indicate that
We conclude that uncertainty affects investment in costly capital in non-standard ways if the firm has access to alternative procurement options. The reason for this is that alternative (less capital intensive) modes of production cap the upside and downside risk associated with capital investment, which in turn alters the effect of uncertainty compared with standard real option models. In addition, access to cheaper outsourcing actually increases the amount of capital invested, given that the firm optimally delays investment until a higher level of demand α is reached. 25
25 With fully reversible capital, the amount of invested capital K under making does not depend on the outsourcing price and increases with p under concurrent sourcing, which is adopted for higher α .
4.4 Operating Leverage
The advantage of this measure of operating leverage is that it is not confounded by product market effects such as the firm’s market power, mark-up as well as the shocks to the demand itself. A quick inspection of Equation (21) reveals that the notion of operating leverage is intrinsically linked to the concept of the economies of scale. Positive (negative) economies of scale are equivalent to the marginal cost being lower (higher) than the average cost, which—in turn—is equivalent to a positive (negative) operating leverage. 26
26 Recall that positive (negative) economies of scale are defined as the presence of a decreasing (increasing) average cost. A decreasing (increasing) average cost is equivalent to the marginal cost being lower (higher) than the average cost.
The operating leverage (OL i ) is depicted in Figure 4 as a function of the demand function parameter α for the set of parameter values as in Section 4.3 and K = 9.338. 27
27 Recall that K = 9.338 is the optimal amount of capital for the base set of parameter values:

Operating leverage (OL i ) is depicted as a function of the demand parameter α for the following set of parameter values: A = 0.2,
Under buying (regime 1),
In regime 2, there are two opposing effects. First, the presence of the fixed cost contributes to a higher operating leverage. This creates a positive spike in operating leverage at
28 Note that
29 We can show that α0 , for which
30 A firm that engages in concurrent sourcing is, in a way, similar to a firm that has a “negative” fixed operating cost equal to the difference between the cost of buying the total internal production (
31 To check robustness, we analyzed different measures of operating leverage. For example,
In summary, operating leverage peaks (reaches a minimum) when the firm switches from buying to making (from making to concurrent sourcing). Firms engaging in concurrent sourcing have negative operating leverage, and their operating leverage is lower than for firms that outsource or firms that produce internally at output levels that are not too high.
4.5 Company Betas and Equity Returns
32 In Appendix C, we consider an extension in which a larger order attracts a bigger discount and
Compare first a firm that can only buy (hereafter “buy-only”) with a firm that can only make (hereafter “make-only”). The beta of a buy-only firm is constant and equal to the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand (i.e.,
33 This result echoes that of Cooper (2006) , who demonstrates that the presence of idle capacity and high book-to-market ratios associated with bad states of the economy lead to higher expected returns. Other explanations for counter-cyclical expected returns include limited operating flexibility due to unionization ( Chen, Kacperczyk, and Ortiz-Molina, 2011 ), higher downside risk ( Bali, Demirtas, and Levy, 2009 ), external habit ( Tallarini and Zhang, 2005 ), and insufficient collateral ( Perez-Quiros and Timmermann, 2000 ).
Why are make-only firms safer than buy-only firms in good states of the economy? The reason is that the internal production function is subject to decreasing returns to scale, 34
34 With increasing returns to scale we would get the opposite result, i.e., make-only firms are riskier than buy-only firms.
35 This relative dampening effect is even stronger if the outsourcing price decreases with the quantity that is bought.
Does operating flexibility lower or raise a firm’s beta? The answer again depends on the state of the economy. In states with high product demand a firm that can engage in concurrent sourcing will have a higher beta than its corresponding counterpart that can only produce the good internally. This result follows from concurrent sourcing being a higher return to scale technology, and therefore also a riskier operating mode, than making. In states with low product demand the beta of a buy-only firm (the natural benchmark for low states) is lower than the beta of a firm that has the flexibility to switch from buying to making, because the latter has the option to switch to a regime with high fixed costs and therefore high operating leverage.
We can now also understand the non-monotonic behavior of beta. Beta is low under buying, and gradually reaches a peak as the firm moves toward making. Under making, beta gradually declines as operating leverage lowers. As diseconomies of scale set in (i.e., the marginal cost exceeds the average cost) beta moves toward a minimum, but then gradually increases again as the firm starts engaging in concurrent sourcing and therefore adopts a higher return to scale technology. Thereafter, beta rises and asymptotes toward the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand. Since beta peaks around the buy-to-make switching point, and reaches a minimum in the neighborhood of the make-to-concurrent sourcing switching point, it follows a characteristic non-monotonic pattern. The main result is summarized in the following corollary:
The beta and expected equity returns of a mature firm are the highest (lowest) when the firm is on the cusp of switching between buying and making (making and concurrent sourcing) .
The behavior of beta is visualized in Figure 5 which plots beta as a function of demand for various levels of volatility. The company beta is generally larger in bad states of the economy than in good states. This effect is more pronounced for low volatility levels as it is more likely then that the firm will stay in a given regime for longer so the regime type will have a stronger influence on beta. 36
36 When volatility is lower (higher), the instantaneous cost structure influences beta more (less) heavily whereas the effect of the options to switch the production regime is smaller (greater).

The beta of the mature firm as a function of the demand parameter α for following set of parameter values:
For sufficiently good states of the economy, the beta of the mature firm that can be flexible regarding the procurement regime it adopts is lower than the beta of an otherwise identical firm that can only rely on outsourcing. This result may be somewhat unexpected as it seemingly contradicts the standard finance textbook argument that a higher fixed to variable cost ratio, which is associated with concurrent sourcing and making, leads to a higher firm risk (see, e.g., Brealey, Myers, and Allen, 2010 , p. 250). The standard argument, however, is based on the implicit assumption of a constant marginal cost, which—in combination with a presence of a fixed cost—results in a positive scale economies and positive operating leverage. Since in our model negative scale economies kick in for a sufficiently high level of output, operating leverage becomes negative, which eventually contributes to beta being lower than under a constant average cost technology (buying).
5. Empirical Implications
Our model has several novel testable implications. Here are the main ones:
Our model predicts that concurrent sourcing is not a “mixed” production strategy that lies somewhere on a continuous make–buy spectrum. Instead, it should be considered a third, distinct strategy used in response to high demand (as it is optimal for
). Our article is therefore capable of explaining the empirical findings of Parmigiani (2007) .Outsourcing activity is likely to display a U-shaped pattern as a function of the state of the economy (as no outsourcing occurs for
). Economic recessions generate outsourcing motivated by cost-cutting, whereas in economic booms firms engage in concurrent sourcing to meet “peak” demand. Domberger (1999) gives an overview of outsourcing activity in a historical context and illustrates that outsourcing occurs in waves.The availability of outsourcing imposes a minimum capital requirement on firms: firms that cannot operate at a sufficiently large scale stop producing internally, irrespective of the state of the economy. Our model therefore predicts that the advent of cheap outsourcing leads to the closure of many small, labor intensive production units. The cheaper it is to buy, the larger the scale required for internal production and the fewer production units survive.
Market-to-book ratio (a proxy for Tobin’s q ) is a poorer predictor of corporate investment (cf. Erickson and Whited, 2000 ) for those sectors or firms that are likely to adopt a less capital intensive technology in response to positive economic shocks.
García-Feijóo and Jorgensen (2010) find a positive association between the degree of operating leverage and stock returns. Novy-Marx (2011) documents that operating leverage predicts returns in the cross-section, and that strategies formed by sorting on operating leverage earn significant excess returns. Our model provides complementary empirical predictions regarding the link between stock returns and operating leverage for firms that can adopt multiple operating strategies:
All else equal, production technologies with higher return to scale parameters generate higher expected stock returns than technologies with lower returns to scale.
All else equal, (dis)economies of scale coincide with (lower) higher expected stock returns.
Betas are counter-cyclical for firms that produce all output internally. Counter-cyclicality of stock betas has been empirically confirmed by Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) , among others.
In economic recessions (booms) betas of firms that can only make output are higher (lower) than betas of firms that can only buy output.
Operating leverage is non-monotonic for firms that can switch to other operating regimes (such as outsourcing and concurrent sourcing). The beta of a firm with different procurement options may therefore display a more complex, non-monotonic behavior. In particular, our model predicts a peak in beta when a firm switches between making and buying. By focusing on a sample of firms that switch from buying to making (or vice versa), one could empirically verify whether there is a statistically significant increase in beta in the run-up (or run-down) to this switch. Similarly, one could test whether firms that engage in concurrent sourcing have, on average, lower expected stock returns than their counterparts that only make or buy. 37
37 Although the current paper does not focus on the financing side of the firm’s activities, the presented model yields a prediction about the expected capital structure following the leverage trade-off option hypothesis (cf. Van Horne (1977) , see also Mandelker and Rhee (1984) and Kahl, Lunn, and Nilsson (2012) ). According to this hypothesis, a change in the production technology associated with an increase in operating leverage is likely to be associated with a reduction of financial leverage in order for the risk of the firm’s equity stock to remain unchanged. As concurrent sourcing results in a lower operating leverage than buying and (largely) making, it is expected to be associated with a higher level of debt than the remaining two regimes.
Due to the presence of regime switching options, procurement flexibility increases the sensitivity of stock beta to market volatility.
While some of our predictions have already been tested and confirmed empirically, many predictions have yet to be explored and could provide the basis for future empirical research.
6. Conclusions
This article examines a firm’s make-or-buy decision assuming that making is subject to fixed production costs and decreasing returns to scale, while buying happens at a constant unit price. We find that three different procurement regimes arise: buying, making, and concurrent sourcing. Firms optimally switch back and forth between regimes in response to economic shocks. Our model shows that concurrent sourcing is an operating strategy that is distinctly separate from buying and making. Capital investment plays an important role in the choice of the optimal procurement mode. A lower level of capital installed makes internal production more expensive compared with buying and this compresses the output demand range over which making is optimal. Therefore, it encourages buying or concurrent sourcing because these operating modes are less capital intensive.
We show that a firm’s procurement strategy affects its operating leverage. Operating leverage is zero if the firm buys all its output from an external supplier. Operating leverage under making declines in the output level: operating leverage is initially strongly positive but becomes negative for high output levels. Operating leverage is negative under concurrent sourcing. Hence, operating leverage peaks (reaches a minimum) when the firm switches from buying to making (from making to concurrent sourcing). This non-monotonic pattern of operating leverage determines the behavior of the stock beta. Beta is low under buying, and gradually reaches a peak as the firm moves toward making. Under making, beta gradually declines as operating leverage lowers. As diseconomies of scale set in, beta moves toward a minimum, but then gradually increases again as the firm starts engaging in concurrent sourcing and therefore adopts a higher return to scale technology. Thereafter, beta rises and asymptotes toward the (absolute value of the) price elasticity of demand. Since beta peaks around the buy-to-make switching point, and reaches a minimum in the neighborhood of the make-to-concurrent sourcing switching point, it follows that the beta follows a characteristic non-monotonic pattern. Low product demand volatility amplifies the stock beta’s peak and through. Positive (negative) scale economies generate higher (lower) beta and higher (lower) expected stock returns.
Our results open up avenues for future research. For instance, our model could be applied to related problems such as a firm’s decision to export or to create productive capacity via foreign direct investment (FDI). The latter usually allows for a lower marginal cost but involves a higher investment in overseas capacity. 38
38 An important paper that discusses FDI in a dynamic context is Kogut and Kulatilaka (1994) who model a multinational firm’s operating flexibility to shift production between two manufacturing plants located in different countries.
Appendix A: Proofs of Propositions
Proof of Proposition 1
We start off by determining
It follows that
As for sufficiently small α buying dominates making, the lower bound of the internal production region,
Proof of Proposition 2
The optimal procurement regime is a function of demand, the cost of buying, and the cost of making. The two former are the same under fully reversible and fixed capital, whereas the latter has an identical functional form (cf. Equations (3) and (10) ). The problem under fully reversible capital is therefore equivalent to the problem under fixed level of capital. Finally, note that under fixed capital, its cost is sunk and not taken into account when making the procurement decision. Under fully reversible capital, its unit cost r is reflected in the cost parameter
Appendix B: Derivation of Value Functions under Uncertainty
39 The solution reflects the fact that the present value of an n -th power of the stochastic variable α is associated with an effective discount rate equal to
Appendix C: Declining Cost of Outsourcing
40 So for ν = 0, we are back to the base case of a constant outsourcing cost.
Solving the above system numerically yields
Since the cost of outsourcing is not constant, the amount of utilized capital and the quantity made under the fully reversible case are going to fluctuate with α even when concurrent sourcing is adopted. This results from the fact that the marginal cost of buying is no longer constant and the marginal cost of making has to follow changes in the former.
References
Author notes
* We thank Steve Young and participants of the Annual Real Options Conference (Rome), the European Economic Association meetings (Glasgow), the Portuguese Finance Association meetings (Ponta Delgada), and the seminar at Aarhus University for helpful comments. Lambrecht is from Judge Business School, University of Cambridge, CB2 1AG, UK. Pawlina is from the Department of Accounting and Finance, Lancaster University, Lancaster LA1 4YX, UK. Teixeira is from Department of Economics and Business, University of the Azores, Rua Mãe de Deus, 9501-801 Ponta Delgada, Portugal. Lambrecht and Pawlina thank the ESRC (grant RES-062-23-0078) and Teixeira thanks Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology (BD/12193/2003) for financial support. Correspondence can be sent to b.lambrecht@jbs.cam.ac.uk .