Abstract

Oligopolistic price-setting has been at the core of antitrust enforcement ever since its existence. Consensus about exempting pure conscious parallelism (tacit collusion) from competition law scrutiny had quickly been reached, which means that non-competitive market conduct by several undertakings is only scrutinized if it was established by certain preceding collusive behavior. The necessary constituents of such illicit collusion, however, are subject to an ongoing debate. This holds particularly true for cases of unilateral collusion where non-competitive market conduct was established based on the individual use of a facilitating practice by (sometimes) only one firm. Competitor-based pricing guarantees by which a company promises to match a competitor’s lower price can serve as an illustration. Economic research shows that such guarantees can impede competition: a firm can deter its rivals from undercutting its price because the resulting quantity effect is lower than usual. At first glance, with “concerted practices'' in Art. 101 TFEU, European competition law provides a suitable tool to tackle such behavior. Under traditional doctrine, however, the concept is not applied to collusion following the individual use of facilitating practices. This notion is put into question, and a new approach distinguishing between (lawful) conscious parallelism and (illegal) unilateral collusion is presented.

I. INTRODUCTION

Frequently described as one of the oldest questions in competition law,1 the distinction between conscious parallelism (tacit collusion or oligopolistic interdependence) and concerted practice (explicit collusion) is far from resolved. It is indeed widely accepted that parallel conduct as such should not be prohibited. Current doctrine in European competition law, therefore, requires undertakings to engage in preceding coordination for subsequent parallel conduct to fall within the scope of Art. 101 TFEU. This is mostly due to the famous remedy problem,2 which arises if one aims at restricting (mere) unilateral market behavior. If the goal was to limit companies in adapting themselves intelligently to their competitor’s behavior, for example, by following a price increase, some counterfactual behavior as an alternative to the prohibited action would have to be prescribed. In cases of joint price hikes without a preceding use of additional means of coordination, this would then quickly lead to a regime of public price stipulation with significant interventions into market forces. Consequently, and rightly so, European competition law is not outcome-based but rather process-based.3 Action is taken not against parallel market conduct itself but against parallel conduct that has been facilitated by additional means of coordination. Typical examples include agreements (cartels), (private) information exchange, or (public) announcement of intended future behavior (“signaling”). Regarding the additional means of coordination that make parallel conduct a concerted practice, current doctrine requires reciprocity between undertakings that take part in a collusive scheme.4 Each and every one of the compromised undertakings needs to be involved in the concertation. Unilateral collusion, that is, parallel conduct established by means of a single, individually applied facilitating practice, is said to fall outside the scope of a concerted practice within Art. 101 TFEU.5

Aside from (perceived) limitations in the wording of Art. 101 TFEU,6 justification can sometimes—again—be found in the previously described remedy problem.7 Without an enforceable remedy, prohibition of certain unilateral behavior is said to be impossible (or at least impractical) because courts or competition agencies would have to dictate an enterprise’s market policy. This train of thought, however, overlooks a crucial fact. If one can identify (at least) one facilitating practice that is separable from the market conduct it aims to influence, there is a suitable target for legal intervention. The remedy problem is solved as soon as one focusses on supplementary means of coordination, irrespectively of how many undertakings (commonly) apply them. Therefore, from a remedy point of view, it is very well possible to take action against unilateral collusion and (ultimately) classify it as a concerted practice.

The following article investigates whether this classification can be established with regard to other methodological constraints of legal interpretation. It takes as a reference point a current example of unilateral collusion, namely competitor-based pricing8 by means of low-price guarantees.9 Early theoretical as well as recent empirical economic evidence suggests that guarantees promising to match a competitor’s cheaper price are capable of restricting competition.10 Such guarantees, however, are often only offered by single undertakings in a given market. Typically, there is no underlying agreement by several undertakings that (at least) one of them starts offering such a guarantee.11

II. CURRENT DOCTRINE: CONCERTED PRACTICES

As a basis for the following investigation, the upcoming section presents current doctrine as well as current boundaries of “concerted practices” under EU competition law. Directly afterwards, the economics of competitor-based pricing will be summarized in order to give a well-documented example of unilateral collusion in real-world settings.

A. Legal Tests

In settled case law, the European Court of Justice (ECJ) describes the character of a concerted practice by means of two key definitions which are frequently labeled the relevant “legal test”.12 In the 1972 dyestuff case13 it held that

the concept of a 'concerted practice' refers to a form of coordination between undertakings which […] knowingly substitutes practical cooperation between them for the risks of competition”.

In the 1975 sugar case14 it went on to state that

although […] (the) requirement of independence does not deprive economic operators of the right to adapt themselves intelligently to the […] conduct of their competitors, it does however strictly preclude any direct or indirect contact between such operators, the object or effect whereof is either to influence the conduct on the market of an actual or potential competitor or to disclose to such a competitor the course of conduct which they themselves have decided to adopt or contemplate adopting on the market”.

It has also been clarified that the concept entails a two-stage criterion. In the 1999 polypropylene cases,15 the ECJ held

that, as is clear from the very terms of Article 85(1) of the Treaty, a concerted practice implies, besides undertakings concerting together, conduct on the market pursuant to those collusive practices, and a relationship of cause and effect between the two.

The causal link between concertation and conduct is subject to a rebuttable presumption,16 even if the concertation has only taken place once.17 While the older definitions have never officially been attributed to either of the two stages by the ECJ itself,18 it follows, as will be elaborated on later, that “practical cooperation” between undertakings describes the parallel market conduct that has resulted from (previous) concertation, whereas this concertation is characterized by “any direct or indirect contact […]” between undertakings. The distinction is relevant regarding the frequently encountered statement that concertation requires practical cooperation and, thus, reciprocal contacts between undertakings.19

B. Boundaries

As has been foreshadowed in the introduction, current doctrine draws the boundaries of concerted practices when being faced with unilateral (individual, one-sided) measures. Disclosure of information does not necessarily need to come about as an actual exchange that would require information to be sent both ways.20 If only one party has revealed information to others, however, a prior act of invitation to send the information in question or a later act of acceptance by the receiving party (or parties) is required.21 Acceptance can be seen in non-opposition if information is shared in a common meeting.22 This is because silence leaves an impression of consensus that ought to be eliminated only by public distancing. This requirement23—letting competitors explicitly know that one does not share the anticompetitive spirit of a meeting and will not behave in accordance with proposed actions—is a general line of jurisprudence that does not only apply in cases of unilateral information disclosures but rather in any anticompetitive meetings where some parties might have remained silent and argue they had not explicitly agreed to the formation of a cartel. An unsolicited message that is not part of a pre-existing communication channel between competitors, however, does not amount to a concerted practice if the recipient does not react.24 In the same vein, a single public announcement of future conduct (“signaling”) does not constitute a concerted practice, even if it appeared obvious that several undertakings followed the announced market conduct later on.25 If at all, only several public announcements (in reaction to another)26 can lead to a concerted practice.

Building on this, a strict distinction has to be made between purely unilaterally facilitated collusion—as addressed in this article—and unilateral disclosure as it was subject to the previously cited cases. While the recent (2023) Horizontal Guidelines by the EU-Commission stay intentionally vague on the matter and seem to suggest that—depending on the facts and merits of the individual case—even the stand-alone announcement of future conduct might constitute a concerted practice,27 both the former case law and the former administrative practice have only ever scrutinized cases with a plurality of announcements by several parties (given in apparent reaction to each other).28

Unilateral collusion—in its intended meaning in this article—should therefore be understood as collusion that is facilitated by the single, individual, stand-alone use of a facilitating practice. It has to be distinguished from instances of a collective29 (albeit one-sided30) use of facilitating practices that can and have already been addressed by current practice.

It is true that the Eturas31ruling represents a borderline case where it might seem that a (purely) unilateral act has been adjudicated as amounting to a concerted practice. The text message and technical constraint implemented by the system administrator, however, was only seen as sufficient concertation in conjunction with the non-opposition of travel agencies gathered on the booking system. The case was therefore solved based on the well-known “public distancing” jurisprudence (see just above). In my opinion, the ruling has not opened the floodgates (yet) for cases that go beyond interactions where (implicit) acceptance of unilateral disclosures can at least somehow be constructed. Instead, the decision was based heavily on context and the collective use of the same booking system by several competitors with an internal message system. It cannot be inferred that the ECJ would come to the same conclusion in cases of pure unilateral action like a stand-alone price-matching guarantee. So far, there have only been cases where courts and agencies managed to squeeze seemingly unilateral actions into a scheme of reciprocity, most notably by identifying some sort of acceptance by the passive-reactive party.

III. COMPETITOR-BASED-PRICING AS AN EXAMPLE

By means of a low-price-guarantee an undertaking can promise to match or to beat a competitor’s cheaper price. Accordingly, such promises are called “price-matching”32 or “price-beating guarantees”33 (PMG/PBG); another pair of terms is “meeting”34 or “beating competition clause”35 (MCC/BCC).

For the purpose of this article, the analysis is narrowed down to PMGs/MCCs. This is due to the fact that economic research has uncovered ambiguous findings for PBGs/BCCs which are (relatively) harder to reconcile with precise policy recommendations for competition law enforcement. For interested readers, the following footnote contains a selection of economic papers dealing with PBGs/BCCs.36

Intuitively, price-matching practices seem beneficial for consumers and imply competitive pressure. If a company lowers its price, others (bound by PMGs) follow immediately which might lead to a market-wide price decrease. At second glance, however, doubts arise as to, which actual incentives these promises; initially addressing customers, carry for competitors. Undercutting a competitor’s price is typically motivated by increased sales. If this quantity effect outweighs the price effect, lowering the price maximizes earnings. However, under a competitor-based-pricing scheme used by a fellow competitor, it is more difficult to divert customers from this competitor. By exercising the guarantee, customers can claim the discounted price from their present supplier without having to switch to the competitor who initially lowered his or her price. Compared to a scenario without PMGs, the quantity effect of their price decrease is lower than usual. Low price guarantees can thus discourage competitors from lowering their prices in the first place.37 If applied by a price leader, by a generally more expensive undertaking, or by an undertaking with a sufficient degree of market power, the price-matching guarantee can be anticompetitive and stabilize supracompetitive price equilibria (collusion hypothesis). Research in economics has shown this for virtually any oligopoly model imaginable.38

This is not to say that low price guarantee harm competition in every situation.39 Another possible explanation for offering such guarantees comes to mind. They could be used to signal real price advantages.40 If a company at the lower range of prices offers a price guarantee, the guarantee might not actually apply. Without a lower advertised price in a given market, no adjustment can be redeemed. Instead, the guarantee can be understood to attract uninformed consumers who do not know actual prices or to serve as insurance for consumers wishing always to buy at the absolute cheapest price. Although a reallocation of consumers in reaction to the guarantee is likely and can change equilibrium prices in the underlying economic models, one can vaguely say that the price matching guarantee by an already cheap competitor has close to no effect on the more expensive competitors. In those cases, PMGs are more or less welfare-neutral on the aggregate level (signaling hypothesis).

Recent empirical evidence shows that both hypotheses can be confirmed in real-world settings. For price matching guarantees by price leaders, there is evidence from German gasoline41 as well as American retail and e-commerce markets pointing to the suspicion that PMGs might be used to decrease competitive pressure by rival companies and deter them from undercutting the firm. In the first case, the studies are particularly interesting because one can observe both phenomena (collusion and signaling) in one market. The guarantee by a price leader (Shell) had an anticompetitive effect on the prices of other branded gas-station networks, whereas the guarantee of a maverick (HEM/Tamoil) had no effect on competitors’ prices because the gas station network already offers competitive prices at the lower bound. In American retail, particularly for consumer electronics, (former) brick-and-mortar-chains seem to have applied price matching guarantees with regard to Amazon’s aggressive pricing strategy on its online marketplace. For different cases (Target and BestBuy),42 it has been documented that, after the introduction of PMGs, Amazon’s prices increased. This is direct evidence of the previously described discouraging effect. The same, in turn, holds true for the promising company. While applying a PMG, their advertising prices are higher than after dropping a PMG policy (NewEgg).43 An in-depth assessment of the papers’ qualities cannot be undertaken in this format. Nonetheless, it has to be mentioned that the reported studies fulfil current econometric standards for causal inference and identification in observed (quasi-experimental) data from natural experiments. Most of them apply difference-in-difference estimators, which happen to be the “gold standard” in lawsuits dealing with damages caused by cartel overcharges.44

Last, but not least, and without going into too much detail, experimental evidence from laboratory oligopoly studies has equally pointed to the fact, that—at least—PMGs have the capacity to support supra-competitive price levels.45

IV. EXTENDING THE SCOPE OF “CONCERTED PRACTICES”

In order to extend the scope of “concerted practices” to cases of unilateral collusion, two steps have to be undertaken. First of all, a more extensive interpretation has to be derived while conforming to methodological standards and boundaries. Second of all, for this alternative interpretation to be implemented, prevailing case law has to be assessed in order to see whether previous rulings and dicta can be upheld or have to be overcome.

A. Interpretation

The legal interpretation will be undertaken from four different perspectives: the origin of the provision, the (comparative) structure of European competition law, the wording, and the purpose (telos) of the norm, including possible consequences.

1. Origin

It can be taken for granted that the term “concerted practice” originates from US antitrust law and entered European competition law via French provenance.46 Although American doctrine has no binding effect on European law and jurisprudence, a look at the American understanding of “concerted action” could nonetheless be indicated under the assumption that the European legislator might have wanted to copy and transpose the concept under its precise meaning. However, in EU law, a norm interpretation based on the legislator’s historic intent is categorically difficult,47 not the least because the authors of the ECCS and EEC treaties decided to exclude the public for thirty years from the archives and the materials documenting the legislative procedures.48 In addition to that, the archives only contain drafts and proposals by member states, no statements, explanations or debates regarding the norms and their wordings.49

There are seven US Supreme Court decisions regarding Section 1 and Section 2 of the Sherman Act, laid down before 1957—when the concept of a “concerted practice” entered into force in European competition law—that contain versions of “concerted action”. In the following section, the legal meaning attached to these words shall be investigated. As a starting point, it has to be recalled that “concerted action” is not part of any of the aforementioned legal provisions. It comes into play when describing “conspiracies” or “attempts to monopolize” in violation of sec. 1 and sec. 2 of the Sherman Act. A “concerted action” has been mentioned for the first time in Eastern States Lumber Association vs. United States50 where the Supreme Court held that

“[…], in order to show a combination or conspiracy within the Sherman Act, some agreement must be shown under which the concerted action is taken.” (at 612).

A similar wording can be found twice in Interstate Circuit, Inc. vs. United States:51

While the District Court’s finding of an agreement of the distributors among themselves is supported by the evidence, we think that in the circumstances of this case such agreement for the imposition of the restrictions upon subsequent-run exhibitors was not a prerequisite to an unlawful conspiracy. It was enough that, knowing that concerted action was contemplated or invited, the distributors gave their adherence to the scheme and participated in it.” (226).

Acceptance by competitors, knowing that concerted action is contemplated, of an invitation to participate in a plan the necessary consequence of which, if carried out, is restraint of interstate commerce is sufficient to establish an unlawful conspiracy under the Sherman Act.” (Ibid, Syllabus, LS. 5).

The same has been repeated in United States vs. Paramount Pictures, Inc.:52

“It is not necessary to find an express agreement in order to find a conspiracy. It is enough that a concert of action is contemplated and that the defendants conformed to the arrangement.” (at 142).

Especially the wording in the later “Hollywood” cases shows that “concerted action” was used to describe parallel conduct, which several enterprises invited each other to or contemplated about. The concertation itself took place under “some agreement” (Eastern States Lumber Association) or via invitation (sent by letter) to participate in a collusive scheme (Hollywood cases), which the parties then adhered to. The decisive legal question concerned the necessary depth of contact between parties. In modern terms, the Supreme Court had to deal with a “hub & spoke” agreement. The distributors did not communicate directly with one another about putting restrictions against subsequently run exhibitors (second-class movie theaters) into place. However, Interstate Circuit had disclosed that it entered into the same negotiations with all distributors. The Supreme Court considered sufficient that the parties knew what was contemplated, even if they had no direct contact. “Concerted action”—understood as the market result—was subject to previous contemplation; however, had no inherent doctrine as to how it was established. It merely described uniform behavior.

This becomes even clearer when looking at the later Tobacco and Theater Enterprise cases. In American Tobacco Co. vs. United States,53 the Supreme Court held that

(w)here the conspiracy is proved, as here, from the evidence of the action taken in concert by the parties to it, it is all the more convincing proof of an intent to exercise the power of exclusion acquired through that conspiracy. (at 809).”

In this case, a conspiracy had been inferred from an (observed) “action taken in concert” that appeared hard to explain without preceding coordination. In Theater Enterprises vs. Paramount Distributing,54 the Supreme Court then restricted an almost exclusive reliance on observed parallel behavior in proving a conspiracy and stated the following:

“The crucial question is whether respondents’ conduct toward petitioner stemmed from independent decision or from an agreement, tacit or express. To be sure, business behavior is admissible circumstantial evidence from which the fact finder may infer agreement […] But this Court has never held that proof of parallel business behavior conclusively establishes agreement or, phrased differently, that such behavior itself constitutes a Sherman Act offense. Circumstantial evidence of consciously parallel behavior may have made heavy in-roads into the traditional judicial attitude toward conspiracy; but “conscious parallelism“ has not yet read conspiracy out of the Sherman Act entirely.” (at 540/1).

From then on, it was clear that a conspiracy could not be inferred based from “(conscious) parallelism” alone. Before that verbal switch, a “concerted action”, “concert of action,” or “action taken in concert” described essentially the same. They referred to parallel market conduct which had either been subject to an agreement or conspiracy (documented using additional proof) or which raised suspicion regarding coordination mechanisms that facilitated such uniform behavior.

In conclusion, at the time of transposition into European competition legislation, “concerted action” has neither been a legal term or concept, nor has it entailed a specific understanding of an underlying coordination mechanism. It simply described parallel conduct, which might have been facilitated by prohibited means of coordination like a preceding agreement or conspiracy. It follows that no guidance for the interpretation of “concerted practices” can be found in US antitrust law.

2. Structure

Sometimes, especially in textbooks and casebooks for educational purposes, competition law is presented using a rather strict dichotomy. Unilateral behavior by a single firm is said to fall (only) under the scope of Art. 102 TFEU (given the dominance of that firm), whereas (only) multilateral behavior by several firms falls under the scope of Art. 101 TFEU.55 The distinction suffers from obvious shortcomings when looking at cases of collective dominance, which is not only recognized in European case law but also explicitly acknowledged in national competition laws by some member states; see, for example, § 18 (5) of the German Act against Restraints of Competition. Apart from that, it is not convincing either to exclude unilateral collusion from Art. 101 TFEU based on the argument that only one party uses a facilitating device. As long as this instrument influences the market conduct, especially the prices of several competing enterprises, it can result in parallel behavior of several parties. Therefore, it is not true that unilateral conduct is an exclusive matter of Art. 102 TFEU, nor is it accurate to label unilateral collusion as an exclusively one-sided phenomenon. While only one-party initiates coordination, it might nonetheless incentivize several parties to adjust their market behavior. The final result then involves several parties.

3. Wording

As has been pointed out prominently, words with a “co-” prefix signal involvement and interaction of several actors. Because many words that are used to describe illicit anticompetitive behavior such as “concertation”, “coordination”, “contact”, “communication”, “collusion”, “consensus”, “concurrence (of wills)” etc. share this common feature, a clear-cut description of what constitutes a “concerted practice” was declared to be missing up to this day.56 Instead, all these words were more or less synonyms or descriptions of one another. For the purpose of this article, two remarks have to be made.

First of all, any (or at least most) of these co-words can be understood in a sender-receiver model of communication where a plurality of actors but no strict reciprocity of action is required. Information might be disclosed or sent by just one person. In order to label the interaction legitimately a “contact”, the information has to be received by at least one other party. This is in line with the non-communicative meaning of “contact” in other scenarios, for example, physics. Two electrodes within an electric circuit being in contact means to be in touch, although electrons flow in just one direction. A physical connection between two items or two human beings does not require reciprocal actions to establish this contact. One party can simply reach out and touch the other.

Secondly, if one takes a look at the literal (albeit nowadays metaphorical) meaning of  “acting in concert”, one can think of an orchestra where several musicians and instruments play in harmony under the direction of one conductor. Although they might have rehearsed their performance before, in the given moment of a performance, their behavior is coordinated or—as one says—orchestrated by one person alone. It is not clear whether all musicians have even spoken once with each other ahead of their concert. Under these circumstances, and in accordance with the initial use of the phrasing in US antitrust enforcement, acting in concert means nothing more than acting jointly or acting together. The wording is neutral as to how the joint action has been established. The interplay between conductor and musicians can serve as the perfect illustration of unilateral collusion where there is one only initiating party, but several adapting parties—the only difference being that, here, the initiator is a third party that is distinct from the group of parties whose behavior is coordinated. This, however, should have no bearing on the inference drawn from this example for (alleged boundaries of) the wording, especially since hub & spoke cartels and the reliance on external cartel facilitators (cf. AC-Treuhand57) have long been recognized in (European) competition law.

4. Purpose/Consequences

4.1. Case Comparison

The discouraging effect of price-matching guarantees on competitors is similar to the effect of price-parity clauses in platform markets for hotel reservations. A booking platform might want to lower its commission rate, hoping that hotels, in turn, will pass on this cost reduction to consumers and offer cheaper room rates on this platform. This might increase transactions on the platform and provide competitive advantages over other platforms. Hotels, however, might not transpose this cost reduction into a cheaper room rate offered on this platform if they have to offer the very same price on another platform that enforces a price-parity clause but did not lower its commission rate. This effect is even stronger if the binding platform has a certain degree of market power and is an important sales channel for the hotel. In this context, charging particularly low fees in order to incentivize hotels to offer cheaper rates might not work. Through this mechanism, a price-parity platform can weaken price competition in commission rates between platforms.58 If a non-binding platform does not obtain a competitive advantage over a binding platform and cannot divert more bookings onto its own platform, it gets discouraged from lowering the commission rate in the first place. Instead, the binding platform might establish price leadership in commission rates.

Consequently, such pricing practices have been subject to competition-law scrutiny all around Europe.59 Because they are part of agreements between undertakings (the platform and the hotel), they can easily be subsumed under Art. 101 TFEU. In fact, not the scope of relevant conduct, but rather the economic effects and distortion of competition (as another element of Art. 101 TFEU) were under question. This perfectly illustrates how current doctrine leads to arbitrary results. Although the economic theory of harm is almost the same, one case can be tackled while the other cannot. This strongly highlights the necessity for a more extensive reading of “concerted practice” under Art. 101 TFEU, not least because it is meant to be an (open) catch-all-provision60 for coordination below agreements.

4.2. Interference with Basic Market and Competition Principles

As the umbrella term already indicates, competitor-based pricing directly ties the prices of two competing undertakings.61 One could also say that—for the number of attentive customers willing to switch or to redeem the guarantee—the promising party delegates its pricing power onto the other company. Just like a monopolist, this party gets to set the prices for both undertakings.62 However, if it stops undercutting because of the discouraging effect, the offering party becomes price leader and effectively sets prices for both undertakings. Both outcomes contradict the competition principle of independent63 action.

If one looks more closely at the discouraging effect of price-matching guarantees, one can also see that it contradicts the law of demand as a basic principle of market economies. According to the law of demand, price decreases yield demand increases (and vice versa).64 However, under a price-matching guarantee, decreasing one’s price does not necessarily increase residual demand anymore. If customers can claim the same price by redeeming a fellow competitor’s guarantee, they do not have to switch to the undertaking which initially lowered its price. This way, price-matching guarantees subvert basic market principles and the downward pricing pressure of competition.

Last, but not least, speaking in terms of competition-law categories, classifying unilateral collusion as a form of tacit collusion (because not every undertaking whose market conduct is eventually influenced actively contributes to the coordination mechanism) overlooks the fact that collusion in these cases has—by no means—been established tacitly. Even if only one firm publicly adopted and announced a price-matching-guarantee, an expressive and overt collusive device has been used. Letting such situations escape competition-law enforcement contradicts the initial distinction between tacit and explicit collusion.

4.3. Remedy Problem

In addition to that, as has already been pointed out in the introduction to this article, the remedy problem cannot serve as an explanation to limit the scope of competition law enforcement in the area of unilateral collusion. Once one has agreed to the two-stage understanding of a “concerted practice”, the famous remedy problem for conscious parallelism has been solved. Having acknowledged the need for separate means of coordination ahead of the resulting parallel market conduct, there is always a suitable target for legal intervention such that one does not encounter the problem of interfering into the (pricing) freedom of market participants. This is irrespective of how many undertakings are engaged in the coordination mechanism. It follows, naturally, that only undertakings that actually used a facilitating practice (the initiators) should be addressed to refrain from such behavior (pursuant to Art. 7(1) and Art. 23(2) of Regulation [EC] 1/2003). This is because the remedy problem still holds for the passive-reactive enterprises which only (“intelligently”/“rationally”) adapt their market conduct.65 Concerns regarding an unfair treatment of these—so to say—compromised undertakings and possible over-deterrence should therefore not be channeled into rejection of a more extensive reading of the substantive provision.66 Rather, these concerns should be solved pleading in favor of cautious norm enforcement and remedies.67

B. Accordance with Case Law

After having shown that a more extensive interpretation of “concerted practices” is not only economically reasonable but also methodologically feasible, in the remainder of this section, it will be shown that this interpretation can be implemented while largely upholding older case law and principles of current doctrine.

1. Two-Stage/Two-Fold Test

First of all, the proposed interpretation can be adopted in line with the two-stage approach to “concerted practices.” Capturing unilateral collusion does not mean abolishing the requirement of parallel (reciprocal) conduct by several competing undertakings in a market. It merely relaxes the requirements in the coordination stage. According to the proposed interpretation, the coordination criterion can already be fulfilled if one undertaking applies facilitating practices, such as a price-matching guarantee. If, in consequence, several undertakings react to this instrument and adapt their market behavior, for example, by following the price leadership of a competitor, there ultimately still results a concerted practice between several undertakings.

The necessary reaction in market conduct by at least one company other than the initiator of a collusive practice might be subject to the ANIC presumption.68 Just like information, once disclosed and perceived, will most likely not be ignored, the same applies to the public announcement of a price-matching guarantee, not only based on this information channel, but also because the guarantee is able to alter demand streams (in case of price decreases by the competitors). Even if competitors did not take notice of the public announcement, they will inevitably notice a change in revenue usually associated with undercutting the competitor. The (potentially) discouraging effect of a price-matching guarantee is therefore independent of verbal notice by the referenced competitors. Yet, it has to be taken into account that the economic effects of PMGs depend on the (market) context. Whether they are collusive or just a signaling device depends on the characteristics of the firm that adapts them (for details, see above). It might, therefore be necessary for enforcers or courts to take a look at the market context in order to determine whether a PMG has the (abstract) capacity to influence the market conduct of other (non-adapting) companies. However, this is neither novel nor due to the proposed extensive interpretation, but a known consequence of the two-stage approach to “concerted practices,” which inevitably leads to an overlap with the later competitive assessments under the prerequisite “prevention, restriction, or distortion of competition.” The extent to which the market result already needs to be assessed as part of the evidence establishing a concerted practice has led to lengthy debates69 in European competition law, which the ECJ – in part – resolved with its ANIC presumption (at least for cases of information exchange). Based on insights from economic research, this assumption could be extended to PMGs of price leaders and relatively more expensive undertakings. In any case, a full-fledged effects analysis at the level of “concerted practices” cannot be required, not least because it would contradict the later necessary investigation of a “prevention, restriction, or distortion of competition” brought about by the “concerted practice” in question. Because there, the provision distinguishes between by-object and by-effect violations – by-object violations only requiring prima-facie (and context) assessments of anti-competitive tendencies –, an earlier investigation as part of the overlapping two-stage-criterion (“concerted practice”) cannot conceptually go any further.

It has to be admitted that the wording “concerting together70 or “concerting with each other71 in the polypropylene formula (see above) can be understood in the spirit of “reciprocal contacts.” However, the passage was never intended to characterize requirements of the coordination stage itself, but rather to confirm the two-stage understanding of a “concerted practice” and the causal relationship between first and second stage. Although these statements have repeatedly been quoted in later cases,72 they have only ever been used to denote that very relation. In contrast, the character of concerted practices is always defined based on the dyestuff-73 (“practical cooperation”) and sugar-formula74 (“direct or indirect contact”) alone. This is why, in the upcoming in-depth analysis, greater emphasis is placed on these two notions.

2. Practical Cooperation

Secondly, it has to be repeated that “practical cooperation,” as it is currently part of the legal test determining a “concerted practice”, does not define the means and the process of coordination. Instead, it describes the result of such concertation. Therefore, it does not oppose an interpretation according to which unilaterally used facilitating practices on the coordination level suffice for an accordingly adjusted market behavior by several undertakings to be considered a concerted practice. The coordination itself does not have to take place in the form of a practical cooperation.

2.1. Wording

On the one hand, this can be inferred from the initial wording of the criterion:

the concept of a ‘concerted practice’ refers to a form of coordination between undertakings which […] knowingly substitutes practical cooperation between them for the risks of competition.”

The ECJ implied a consecutive relationship (“substitutes”) between the coordination among undertakings and the practical cooperation (joint conduct) which replaces the risks of competition (individual, independent behavior). Had the ECJ wanted to define the “forms of coordination” itself, other wordings would have been more precise, such as “form of coordination […]” which consist of “practical cooperation” or present themselves as “practical cooperation.”

The fact that practical cooperation has to be understood as the resulting market conduct can also be seen in a quote from the later sugar case:75

Such practical cooperation amounts to a concerted practice […], if […].”

As a whole, a concerted practice describes a market outcome. Practical cooperation that can amount to a concerted practice—if certain (additional) requirements are fulfilled—is therefore also located on the resulting market level.

In addition to that, the ECJ later on has always cited the two criteria separately, not as versions describing the same subject.

The Court also stated […] that the criteria of coordination and cooperation necessary for the existence of a concerted practice in no way require the working out of an actual ‘plan’ […].“76

Distinguishing “coordination” from “practical cooperation” implies different scopes of application for these requirements. Were they both to describe the same illicit behavior, different wordings would—again—have been more precise, such as: “coordination in the form of practical cooperation.”77

2.2. Context

On the other hand, this interpretation is in line with the case context from which the initial phrasing originates. In the dyestuff ruling, several joint price hikes had been observed, because of which preceding coordination had been suspected and partially identified in reciprocal public announcements of future pricing intention.78 If one reads a less popular section of the ruling,79 the previously mentioned context highlights that (practical) cooperation describes the resulting market conduct.

In these circumstances and taking into account the nature of the market in the products in question, the conduct of the applicant [price announcements; note by author], in conjunction with other undertakings against which proceedings have been taken, was designed to replace the risks of competition and the hazards of competitors’ spontaneous reactions by cooperation [joint price increases; note by author] constituting a concerted practice prohibited by Article 85(1) of the Treaty.”

2.3. Merging Formulas

Last, but not least, the dyestuff and sugar formulas have been merged80 in the polypropylen cases. Thereby, the definition of coordination from the sugar case has hence been complemented with a statement81 from the dyestuff case, narrowing down the relevant forms of practical cooperation.

According to that case-law, although that requirement of independence does not deprive economic operators of the right to adapt themselves intelligently to the existing and anticipated conduct of their competitors, it does however strictly preclude any direct or indirect contact between such operators, the object or effect whereof is either to influence the conduct on the market of an actual or potential competitor or to disclose to such a competitor the course of conduct which they themselves have decided to adopt or contemplate adopting on the market, where the object or effect of such contact is to create conditions of competition which do not correspond to the normal conditions of the market in question, regard being had to the nature of the products or services offered, the size and number of the undertakings and the volume of the said market […].”82

This allows for conclusions regarding the relationship of coordination and cooperation and again shows that the underlying coordination of a concerted practice is not defined as a practical cooperation. Rather, coordination on the concertation level results in practical cooperation on the market level.

3. Direct or Indirect Contact

Third and last, the wording of the sugar formula does not prescribe reciprocal behavior. According to the ECJ, the requirement of independence precludes any direct or indirect contact, the object or effect of which is to influence a competitor’s behavior or to announce one’s own intended future conduct. As already stated, contact indeed requires a sender and receiver of information and thus two parties involved. However, the action of just one party, establishing this contact, suffices to fulfil this definition.83 Consequently, individual behavior such as a single price-matching guarantee can be subsumed.

4. Conclusion

In accordance with current case law, purely unilateral conduct—as defined in this article—can trigger a concerted practice. In other words: The concerted practice of several companies can be initiated by a single undertaking as long as it managed to impact the market conduct of others. Because it is sufficient that only one company used a facilitating practice (for example, it advertises a price-matching guarantee), there is no (general) need to demonstrate any sort of acceptance by the other parties on the coordination stage (for example, based on pricing conduct). Pricing conduct is only relevant in the second stage regarding the question OF whether the collusive behavior in the coordination stage had an impact on the market conduct of other entities. That question comes with its own burden of proof and presumptions (most notably: ANIC). In cases of a (unilateral) information disclosure or public announcement, the presumption of consideration and influence on the market conduct might, of course, be limited to cases where there is at least some sort of invitation or ambiguous reaction of the receiving party.

V. SUMMARY

As has been pointed out in the paper, a “concerted practice” can be understood as parallel conduct by several parties that has been facilitated by a collusive device, even if that device has only been applied (unilaterally) by a single enterprise among the group of concerned undertakings. The concept had no inherent doctrine when it was imported from US antitrust law. Neither the wording nor the structure of EU competition law opposes this view. The more extensive reading proposed in this article is not only indicated from an economic point of view but also follows the principle of consistency when comparing similar cases. Last but not least, the remedy problem does not generally apply to unilateral collusion and cannot justify a restrictive view.

VI. OUTLOOK

The suggested, more extensive interpretation has implications reaching far beyond the given example of competitor-based pricing guarantees, of which only some shall be mentioned.

If one takes a look at “hub & spoke”–concertation for example, the Eturas ruling84 has been criticized regarding the way it established the necessary contact between travel agencies on a booking system and held them accountable for a message and technical constraint which was implemented by the system administrator. The ECJ assumed that under ordinary circumstances, corporate users take account of these messages. Participation in the collusive arrangement was then seen in non-opposition to the proposal.85 While, in my opinion, this interpretation is well in line with previous case law on public distancing after participation in anti-competitive meetings,86 the required minimum necessary conduct for an undertaking to be part of a concertation scheme is still under dispute. If one believes that “reciprocal contacts87 between undertakings are necessary, then the ruling can indeed be seen critically. If, on the contrary, one follows the suggested interpretation in this article and agrees that unilateral acts of coordination suffice, it is not necessary to find collusive behavior by all involved market participants. Rather, it is sufficient to show that a unilateral measure by one undertaking had an impact on the market conduct of other undertakings. This is in line with the ECJ’s argument that most of the platforms conformed to the technical rebate constraint and did not override it individually. Consequently, the travel agencies took part in a concerted practice although—as indicated above—they should not be held liable to the same extent as the initiator (system administrator), not least because the remedy problem applies to them.88

In the same vein, it becomes easier for competition authorities to deal with cases of “signaling”89 by means of public announcements. So far, authorities have largely90 refrained from taking on cases in which single (stand-alone) public statements of companies might have facilitated a joint price hike by several enterprises. Instead, they focused on cases of collective public announcements that were published in reaction to another.91 In the old Horizontal Guidelines from 2011, the EU-Commission stated that the exemption of an individual announcement of future conducts from antitrust scrutiny only holds if it does not contain an “invitation to collude.92 While a clear-cut definition of what in fact constitutes such an invitation is already missing, it also remains unclear how a single individual public invitation to collude can be squeezed into the requirement of “reciprocal contacts”, which many scholars and practitioners read into a “concerted practice.” The more extensive interpretation proposed in this article offers possible new grounds for interventions against such “invitations to collude”,93 if deemed necessary.

Another case of unilateral collusion can be seen in the phenomenon of “sticky leadership pricing” which has been documented both empirically94 and investigated legally.95  De lege lata, the authors felt constrained by current doctrine and suggested changes to European competition law de lege ferenda:96

Our results imply the necessity of stronger legal instruments that target unilateral conduct that aims at bringing about collusion.”

Following my approach, European competition law might already be equipped with an effective tool.

Footnotes

1

Thomas, S. 2022. Rechtliche und wettbewerbspolitische Bewertung des § 32f RefE 11. GWB-Novelle, Zeitschrift für Wettbewerbsrecht, 20:333, 339; Grillo, M. 2002. Collusion and Facilitating Practices: A New Perspective in Antitrust Analysis, European Journal of Law & Economics, 14:151, 151; Korah, V. 1999. Gencor v. Commission: Collective Dominance, European Competition Law Review, 20:337, 337.

2

Turner, D.F. 1962. The Definition of Agreement under the Sherman Act: Conscious Parallelism and Refusals to Deal, Harvard Law Review, 75:665–673.

3

Lianos, I., Korah, V., Siciliani, P. Competition Law—Analysis, Cases and Materials, 1st edn, 2019, p. 367.

4

Albors-Llorens, A. 2006. Horizontal Agreements and Concerted Practices in EC Competition Law: Unlawful and Legitimate Contacts Between Competitors, Antitrust Bulletin, 51:837, 851, 858.

5

For potential scrutiny under Art. 102 TFEU, see: Gjendemsjø, R., Hjelmeng, E.J., Sørgard, L. 2013. Abuse of Collective Dominance: The Need for a New Approach, World Competition, 36:355–371; Petit, N. 2007. Oligopoles, Collusion Tacite et Droit Communautaire de la Concurrence, p. 432, 447 subs.; Stroux, S. 2004. US and EC Oligopoly Control, p. 168 subs., Chapter 7, Section 6: Unilateral Adoption of Facilitating Practices under Art. 82 of the EC-Treaty; Monti, G. 2001. The Scope of Collective Dominance under Articles 82 EC, Common Market Law Review, 38:131, 146 subs.; Vecchi, T. 2008. Unilateral Conduct in an Oligopoly according to the Discussion Paper on Art. 82: Conscious Parallelism or Abuse of Collective Dominance? World Competition, 31:385, 397.

6

Regarding the German version, see for example Lettl, T. 2017. Abstimmung im Sinne von Art. 101 Abs. 1 AEUV, § 1 GWB, Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 422,425; Kumkar, L.K. 2023. In Beckscher Online Kommentar zum Informations- und Medienrecht, 42nd edn, TFEU Art. 101 rec. 22.

7

Paschke, M. 2023. In Münchener Kommentar zum Wettbewerbsrecht, Vol. 1, 4th edn, 2023, Art. 101 TFEU, rec. 174 and Vol. 2, 4th edn, 2022, § 1 GWB rec. 144; potentially also Marchisio, E. 2017. From Concerted Practices to Invitations to Collude, European Competition Law Review, 38:555, 560.

8

For the term, see Mago, S.D., Pate, J.G. 2009. An Experimental Examination of Competitor-Based Price Matching Guarantees, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70:342–360; Simons, J.J. 1989. Fixing Price with Your Victim: Efficiency and Collusion with Competitor-Based Formula Pricing Clauses, Hofstra Law Review, 17:599 or Belton, T.M. 1987. A Model of Duopoly and Meeting or Beating Competition, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5:399, 400.

9

See for the term Arbatskaya, M. 2001. Can Low-Price Guarantees Deter Entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 42:1387–1406, footnote 1.

10

For two (albeit slightly outdated) policy reports, see OFT-report 1438 “Can ‘Fair’ Prices Be Unfair? A Review of Price Relationship Agreements” issued by LEAR consultants on behalf of the Office of Fair Trade (now Competition and Markets Authority, CMA) in September 2012 as well as Arnold, T., Baake, P., Schwalbe, U. Preisgarantien im Einzelhandel: Nicht Verbraucher-Freundlich, sondern ein Instrument zur Durchsetzung hoher Preise, DIW-WOCHENBERICHT Nr. 16/2012.

11

Interpreting the guarantee as an agreement between undertaking and the other market side (for US Antitrust c.f. Edlin, A.S. 1997. Do Guaranteed-Low-Price Policies Guarantee High Prices, And Can Antitrust Rise To Challenge? Harvard Law Review, 111:528, 555 subs.; Simons, J.J. 1989. Fixing Price with Your Victim: Efficiency and Collusion with Competitor-Based Formula Pricing Clauses, Hofstra Law Review, 17:599, 630 subs.) does not help either, because consumers fall outside the personal scope of Art. 101 TFEU, see Gjendemsjø, R., Hjelmeng, E.J., Sørgard, L. 2013. Abuse of Collective Dominance: The Need for a New Approach, World Competition, 36:355, 363 and Zimmer, D. 2023. In Immenga/Mestmäcker, Wettbewerbsrecht, Vol. 2: GWB, 7th edn, § 1 rec. 259 subs. with specific regard to competitor-based pricing.

12

Whish, R., Bailey, D. 2021. Competition Law, 10th edn, p. 118.

13

ECJ, 14.07.1972, 48/69, rep. 1972–00619, ECLI:EU:C:1972:70—ICI, para. 64/67.

14

ECJ, 16.12.1975, 40–48/73 and others, rep. 1975–01663, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174—Suiker Unie, para. 174.

15

ECJ, 8.7.1999, C-49/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4125, ECLI:EU:C:1999:356—Anic Partecipazioni, para. 118 subs.; C-199/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4287, ECLI:EU:C:1999:358—Hüls, para. 161 subs. (“concerting with each other”); C-235/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4539, ECLI:EU:C:1999:362—Montecatini, para. 125 subs.

16

Ibid.

17

ECJ, 4.6.2009, C-8/08, rep. 2009 I-4529, ECLI:EU:C:2009:343—T-Mobile Netherlands, para. 51, 62.

18

See, however, German Federal Court of Justice (BGH), 13.07.2020, KRB 99/19—Beer cartel, para. 20: “A concerted practice contains a two-fold legal test. Apart from a concertation (contact), it requires an actual conduct in the sense of a practical cooperation on the market, that is, a concrete market conduct implementing the concertation.” (translated from German by the author).

19

Previously Roth, W.H., Ackermann, T. In Frankfurter Kommentar zum Kartellrecht, Grundfragen des Art. 81 Abs. 1 EG, 68th delivery from 05/2009, rec. 188: “A ‘cooperation’ requires reciprocity of relevant actions by all involved parties.” (translated from German); now (101st delivery from 03/2022), however, to the contrary: “A ‘cooperation’ does not require reciprocity in relevant actions by all involved parties.” (translated from German); Dreher, M., Hoffmann, J. 2011. Kartellrechtsverstöße durch Informationsaustausch, Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 1181:1184; see also Jones, A., Sufrin, B., Dunne, N. 2019. EU Competition Law, 7th edn, p. 177: “Reciprocal cooperation,” although they do not mix up coordination and cooperation.

20

General Court (EU), 24.03.2011, T-377/06, ECLI:EU:T:2011:108—Comap/Kommission, para. 70; EU-Commission, Official Journal, 21.07.2023, C 259 (Horizontal Guidelines), p. 83, rec. 395.

21

General Court (EU), 15.03.2000, T-25/95 and others, rep. 2000 II-00491, ECLI:EU:T:2000:77—Cimenteries, para. 1849, 1887; Whish, R., Bailey, D. 2021. Competition Law, 10th edn; Marchisio, E. 2017. From Concerted Practices to Invitations to Collude, European Competition Law Review, 38:555, 559 subs.

22

General Court (EU), 12.07.2001, T-202/98 and others, rep. 2001 II-02035, ECLI:EU:T:2001:185—Tate & Lyle/Commission, rec. 54 subs.

23

Settled case law: ECJ, 19.03.2009, C-510/06, rep. 2009 I-1843, ECLI:EU:C:2009:166—ADM/Commission, para. 119; ECJ, 07.01.2004, C-204/00 and others, rep. 2004 I-403, ECLI:EU:C:2004:6—Aalborg Portland/Commission, para. 81 subs.; confirmed by: General Court, 29.06.2012, T-360/09, ECLI:EU:T:2012:332—E.ON Ruhrgas/Commission, para. 176; previously already General Court, 05.12.2006, T-303/02, rep. 2006 II-4567, ECLI:EU:T:2006:374—Westfalen Gassen Nederland/Commission, para. 101 subs.; General Court, 11.12.2003, T-61/99, rep. 2003 II-5349, ECLI:EU:T:2003:335—Adriatica di Navigazione/Kommission, para. 138; General Court, 06.04.1995, T-142/89, rep. 1995 II-867, ECLI:EU:T:1995:63—Boël/Kommission, para. 60; from the literature see Bailey, D. 2008. “Publicly Distancing” Oneself from a Cartel, World Competition, 31:177; Abenhaïm, M. 2016. Public Distancing and Liability in Cartel Cases: Does Distance Lend Enchantment?, World Competition, 39:413.

24

EU-Commission, Official Journal, 21.07.2023, C 259 (Horizontal Guidelines), p. 83, rec. 397 (text box, second example).

25

EU-Commission, Official Journal, 14.1.2011, C 11/1 (Old Horizontal Guidelines), rec. 63; possibly to the contrary, see Dutch Authority for Consumers and Markets (ACM), settlement decision, 7.1.2014, case docket 13.06126.53—Mobile Operators.

26

Case law: ECJ, 31.03.1993, C-89/85 and others, rep. 1993 I-01307, ECLI:EU:C:1993:120—Ahlström; ECJ, 14.07.1972, 48/69, rep. 1972–00619, ECLI:EU:C:1972:70—ICI; administrative practice: EU-Commission, 07.07.2016, AT.39850—Container Shipping, rec. 35 subs., 45 subs.; German Federal Cartel Office (BKartA), Final report regarding a sec. 32e GWB decision, B1–73/13, July 2017, p. 240 susb.; Irish Competition and Consumer Protection Commission (CCPC), press statement from 20.08.2021, “Motor insurers set to introduce new compliance measures following CCPC investigation” (https://www.ccpc.ie/business/motor-insurers-set-to-introduce-new-compliance-measures-following-ccpc-investigation/).

27

EU-Commission, Official Journal, 21.07.2023, C 259 (Horizontal Guidelines), p. 84, rec. 398 first sentence.

28

See already the EU-Commission, Official Journal, 21.07.2023, C 259 (Horizontal Guidelines), p. 84, rec. 398 third sentence and the following text box speaking about several parties or representatives publicly commenting on price-sensitive issues.

29

“Collective” indicating a plurality of actions by more than one party (as opposed to individual).

30

“One-sided” indicating separate (and as such isolated) action by a party as opposed to multi-sided action by several parties in a common scheme (such as common meetings).

31

ECJ, 21.01.2016, C-74/14, ECLI:EU:C:2016:42—Eturas.

32

See, for example, Moorthy, S., Winter, R.A. 2006. Price-Matching Guarantees, Rand Journal of Economics, 37:449–465.

33

See, for example, Buccirossi, P. In Buccirossi (ed.), Handbook of Antitrust Economics, 2008, Chapter 8: Facilitating Practices, p. 305, 335.

34

See for example Salop, S. Practices that (credibly) facilitate oligopoly coordination, FTC Working Paper No. 73, printed In Stiglitz, Mathewson (eds), New Developments in the Analysis of Market Structure, 1986, p. 265, 279 subs.

35

See for example: Belton, T.M. 1987. A Model of Duopoly and Meeting or Beating Competition, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5:399, 400.

36

Theoretical: Doyle, C. 1988. Different Selling Strategies in Bertrand Oligopoly, Economics Letters, 28:387, 390; Hviid, M., Shaffer, G. 1994. Do Low-Price Guarantees Facilitate Collusion, Warwick Economic Research Paper Series (TWERPS), 422, p. 5; Baye, M., Kovenock, D. 1994. How to Sell a Pickup truck: “Beat-or-Pay” Advertisements as Facilitating Devices, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 12:21; Corts, K.S. 1995. On the Robustness of the Argument that Price-Matching is Anti-Competitive, Economics Letters, 47:417–421; Chen, Z. 1995. How Low Is a Guaranteed-Lowest-Price, Canadian Journal of Economics, 28:683–701; Edlin, A.S. 1997. Do Guaranteed-Low-Price-Policies Guarantee High Prices, and Can Antitrust Rise to Challenge?, Harvard Law Review, 111:528, 531, footnote. 9; Kaplan, T.R. 2000. Effective Price-Matching: A Comment, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18:1291–1294; Buccirossi, P. In Buccirossi (ed.), Handbook of Antitrust Economics, 2008, Chapter 8: Facilitating Practices, p. 305, 335 subs.; Liu, Q. 2013. Tacit Collusion with Low-Price Guarantees, The Manchester School, 81:828, 842; empirical: Arbatskaya, M., Hviid, M., Shaffer, G. 1999. Promises to Match or Beat the Competition: Evidence from Retail Tire Prices, Advances in Applied Microeconomics, 8:123–138; Arbatskaya, M., Hviid, M., Shaffer, G. 2004. On the Incidence and Variety of Low-Price Guarantees: A Test for Pairwise–Facilitation, Journal of Law & Economics, 47:307, 315; Arbatskaya, M., Hviid, M., Shaffer, G. 2006. On the Use of Low-Price Guarantees to Discourage Price-Cutting; International Journal of Industrial Organization 24:1139–1156; Máñez, J.A. 2006. Unbeatable Value Low Price Guarantee: Collusion Mechanism or Advertising Strategy, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 15:143–166; experimental: Deck, C.A., Wilson, B.J. 2003. Automated Pricing Rules in Electronic Posted Offer Markets, Economic Inquiry, 41:208–223; Fatás, E., Georgantzís, N., Máñez, J.A., Sabater-Grande, G. 2005. Procompetitive Price Beating Guarantees: Experimental Evidence, Review of Industrial Organization, 26:115–136; Fatás, E., Georgantzís, N., Máñez, J.A., Sabater-Grande, G. 2013. Experimental Duopolies Underprice Guarantees, applied Economics, 45:15–35.

37

Salop, S. Practices That (Credibly) Facilitate Oligopoly Coordination, FTC Working Paper No. 73, printed in: Stiglitz, J.E., Mathewson, F. (eds), New Developments in the Analysis of Market Structure, 1986, p. 265, 279 subs., was the first to point this out; Buccirossi, P. In Buccirossi (ed.), Handbook of Antitrust Economics, 2008, Chapter 8: Facilitating Practices, p. 305, 335 subs.; for references in US Antitrust scholarship see for example: Simons, J.J. 1989. Fixing Price with Your Victim: Efficiency and Collusion with Competitor-Based Formula Pricing Clauses, Hofstra Law Review, 1989:599; Sargent, M.T.L. 1993. Economics Upside Down: Low Price Guarantees as Mechanisms for Facilitating Tacit Collusion, University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 141:2055; Edlin, A.S. 1997. Do Guaranteed-Low-Price-Policies Guarantee High Prices, And Can Antitrust Rise To Challenge?, Harvard Law Review, 111:528; Corcoran, M.A. 2003. Guaranteeing High Prices by Guaranteeing the Lowest Price, Ohio State Law Journal, 64:1427; for references in German scholarship, see Schwalbe, U., Zimmer, D. 2021. Kartellrecht und Ökonomie, 3rd edn, p. 534 subs.; Ewald, C. In Wiedemann, G. (ed.), Handbuch des Kartellrechts, 4th edn, 2020, § 7 rec. 98; Zimmer, D. In Immenga/Mestmäcker, Wettbewerbsrecht, Vol. 2: German Act against Restraints of Competition, 7th edn, 2023, § 1 rec. 259 subs.; Kerber, W., Schwalbe, U. In Münchener Kommentar zum Wettbewerbsrecht, Vol. 1: EU-Law, 4th edn, 2023, Chapter: Foundations, rec. 337, 367.

38

Static price competition with homogeneous goods: Doyle, C. 1988. Different Selling Strategies in Bertrand Oligopoly, Economics Letters, 28:387; Chen, Z. 1995. How Low Is a Guaranteed-Lowest-Price, Canadian Journal of Economics, 28:683–701; Trost, M. The Collusive Efficacy of Competition Clauses in Bertrand Markets with Capacity-Constrained Retailers, Hohenheim Discussion Papers in Business, Economics and Social Sciences, 2021–04 and Trost, M. Unraveling the Spreading Pattern of Collusively Effective Competition Clauses, Hohenheim Discussion Papers in Business, Economics and Social Sciences, 2022–01 (including capacity constraints); static price competition with differentiated goods: Logan, J.W., Lutter, R.W. 1989. Guaranteed Lowest Prices: Do They Facilitate Collusion?, Economics Letters, 31:189–192; Hviid, M., Shaffer, G. 1999. Hassle Costs: The Achilles’ Heel of Price-Matching Guarantees, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 8:489–521; Kim, J.Y., Kwong, J.Y. 2018. Guaranteed Lowest Prices: Do They Facilitate Collusion?, Revisited, Economic Research, 31:899–907; Stackelberg competition with homogeneous goods: Belton, T.M. A 1987. Model of Duopoly and Meeting or Beating Competition, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5:399–418; Hotelling competition: Zhang, Z.J. 1995. Price-Matching Policy and the Principle of Minimum Differentiation, Journal of Ind. Economics, 43:287–299; Baake, P., Schwalbe, U. 2013. Price Guarantees, Consumer Search, and Hassle Costs, In Beiträge zur Jahrestagung des Vereins für Socialpolitik: Wettbewerbspolitik und Regulierung in einer globalen Wirtschaftsordnung—Session: Oligopoly No. G14-V1; Trost, M. 2016. Price-Matching Guarantees of Price Leaders, Working Paper; dynamic competition with homogeneous goods: Lu, Y., Wright, J. 2010. Tacit Collusion with Price-Matching Punishments, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 28:298–306; Garrod, L. 2012. Collusive Price Rigidity under Price-Matching Punishments, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 30:471–482; dynamic competition with differentiated products: Liu, Q. 2013. Tacit Collusion with Low-Price Guarantees, The Manchester School, 81:828, 842.

39

See for a nuanced, less critical account of possible constellations: Winter, R.A. Price–Matching and Meeting Competition Guarantees, In American Bar Association, Section of Antitrust Law (ed.), Issues in Competition Law and Policy, 2008, Vol. 2, p. 1269 subs.

40

C.f. Jain, S., Srivastava, J. 2000. An Experimental and Theoretical Analysis of Price-Matching Refund Policies, Journal of Marketing Research, 37:351–362; Moorthy, S., Winter, R.A. 2006. Price-Matching Guarantees, Rand Journal of Economics, 37:449–465; Moorthy, S., Zhang, X. 2006. Price Matching by Vertically Differentiated Retailers: Theory and Evidence, Journal of Marketing Research, 43:156–167.

41

Dewenter, R., Schwalbe, U. 2016. Preisgarantien im Kraftstoffmarkt, Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik, 17:276–288; Wilhelm, S. 2019. Price Matching and Edgeworth Cycles, Working Paper; Cabral, L.M.B., Dürr, N., Schober, D., Woll, O. 2021. Price Matching Guarantees and Collusion: Theory and Evidence from Germany, CEPR Discussion Papers, 15823.

42

Zhuo, R. 2017. Do Low-Price Guarantees Guarantee Low Prices? Evidence from Competition between Amazon and Big-Box Stores, Journal of Industrial Economics, 65:719–738.

43

Bottasso, A., Marocco, P., Robbiano, S. 2023. Price Matching in Online Retail, GLO Discussion Paper, No. 1351.

44

See for example Nils, G., Jenkins, H., Kavanagh, J. 2023. Economics for Competition Lawyers, 3rd edn, Chapter 10.

45

Dugar, S., Sorensen, T. 2006. Hassle Costs, Price-Matching Guarantees and Price Competition: An Experiment, Review of Industrial Organization, 28:359–378; Fatás, E., Máñez, J.A. 2007. Are Low-Price Promises Collusion Guarantees? Spanish Economic Review, 9:59–77; Dugar, S. 2007. Price-Matching Guarantees and Equilibrium Selection in a Homogenous Product Market: An Experimental Study, Review of Industrial Organization; 30:107–119; Mago, S.D., Pate, J.G. 2009. An Experimental Examination of Competitor-Based Price Matching Guarantees, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organizatio; 70:342–360; Pollak, A. 2017. Do Price-Matching Guarantees with Markups Facilitate Tacit Collusion? Theory and Experiment, University of Cologne Working Paper Series in Economics, No. 93; see also the meta-study by Engel, C. 2015. Tacit Collusion: The Neglected Experimental Evidence, Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 12:537, 555 subs., 562: “In the presence of a price matching guarantee, collusion doubles.”

46

Ordonnance n°45–1483 du 30 juin 1945 relative aux prix; cf. Art. 59: “actions concertées”; see also Mestmäcker, E.-J., Schweitzer, H. 2014. Europäisches Wettbewerbsrecht, 3rd edn, § 10 rec. 33.

47

Precisely for the realm of competition law see the opinion by Advocate General Vesterdorf, 10.07.1991, T-1/89, rep. 1991 II-867, p. 928—Rhône-Poulenc.

48

Mestmäcker, E.J., Schweitzer, H. 2014. Europäisches Wettbewerbsrecht, 3rd edn, § 2 rec. 14; see for the disclosure procedure: Council Regulation (EEC, Euratom) No 354/83 of 1 February 1983, Official Journal No. L 43, p. 1–3 and Commission Decision No 359/83/ECSC of 8 February 1983, Official Journal No. L 43, p. 14 subs.

49

Extracts can be found in Schulze, R., Hoeren, T. (eds) 2000. Dokumente zum Europäischen Recht, Vol. 3 (Competition Law until 1957); see also Ellis, J.J.A. 1963. Source Material for Article 85(1) of the EEC Treaty, Fordham Law Review, 32:247–278.

50

234 U.S. 600 (1914); then again in Column & Lumber Co. vs. United States, 257 U.S. 377, 400 (1921); previously the term had already been used in 1910 in Grenada Lumber Co. vs. Mississippi, 217 U.S. 433 (1910), which, however, was a case assessed under Mississippi state law, not the (federal) Sherman Act.

51

306 U.S. 208 (1939); c.f. Einer Elhauge/Damien Geradin, Global Competition Law and Economics, 2007, p. 762 subs.

52

334 U.S. 131 (1948).

53

328 U.S. 781 (1946).

54

346 U.S. 537 (1954).

55

In German scholarship, cf. Lettl, T. 2017. Abstimmung im Sinne von Art. 101 Abs. 1 AEUV, § 1 GWB, Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb, 422:425; Marchisio, E. 2017. From Concerted Practices to Invitations to Collude, European Competition Law Review, 38:555, 560 acknowledging, however, in line with this article, that the requirement of multilateral behavior under Art. 101 TFEU only needs to be fulfilled with regard to the subsequent market conduct.

56

Black, O. 2005. Communication, Concerted Practices and the Oligopoly Problem, European Competition Journal, 1:341; Black, O. Conceptional Foundations of Antitrust, 2005, p. 141 subs.

57

ECJ, 22.10.2015, C- 194/14 P, ECLI:EU:C:2015:717—AC-Treuhand/Commission.

58

van der Veer, J.P. 2013. Antitrust Scrutiny of Most-Favored-Customer Clauses: An Economic Analysis, Journal of European Competition Law and Practice, 4:501; Zimmer, D., Blaschczok, M. 2014. Most-Favored-Customer Clauses and Two-Sided Platforms, Journal of European Competition Law and Practice, 5:187; Colangelo, M. 2017. Parity Clauses and Competition Law in Digital Marketplaces: The Case of Online Hotel Booking, Journal of European Competition Law and Practice, 8:3; Mantovani, A., Piga, C., Reggiani, C. 2018. On the Economic Effects of Price Parity Clauses—What Do We Know Three Years Later?, Journal of European Competition Law and Practice, 9:650; Akman, P. 2016. A Competition Law Assessment Of Platform Most-Favored-Customer Clauses, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 12:781; Caccinelli, C., Toledano, J. 2018. Assessing Anticompetitive Practices in Two-Sided Markets: The Booking.Com Cases, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 14:193; Ezrachi, A. 2015. The Competitive Effects of Parity Clauses on Online Commerce, European Competition Journal, 11:488.

59

For Germany see for example: Federal Court of Justice, 18.05.2021, KVR 54/20—Booking; Higher Regional (Appellate) Court of Düsseldorf, 09.01.2015, VI-Kart 1/14 (V)—HRS-Bestpreisklausel; see lately also ECJ, 19.09.2024, C-264/23, ECLI:EU:C:2024:764—Booking.

60

Mestmäcker, E.J., Schweitzer, H. 2014. Europäisches Wettbewerbsrecht, 3rd edn, § 10 rec. 36

61

Scott Morton, F. Contracts That Reference Rivals, Antitrust, 27:72, (2013).

62

Salop, S. 1986. Practices That (Credibly) Facilitate Oligopoly Coordination, FTC Working Paper No. 73, printed In Stiglitz/Mathewson (eds), New Developments in the Analysis of Market Structure, p. 265, 281; Hovenkamp, H. 2017. Principles of Antitrust, 2nd edn, p. 157; see also Moorthy, S., Winter, R.A. 2006. Price-Matching Guarantees, Rand Journal of Economics, 37:449, 451, 461: “delegating their pricing decision” or Belton, T.M. 1987. A Model of Duopoly and Meeting or Beating Competition, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 5:399 and Zhang, Z.J. 1995. Price-Matching Policy and the Principle of Minimum Differentiation, Journal of Industrial Economics, 43:287, 294.

63

ECJ, 16.12.1975, 40–48/73 and others, rep. 1975–01663, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174—Suiker Unie: “The criteria of coordination and cooperation laid down by the case-law of the Court, which in no way require the working out of an actual plan, must be understood in the light of the concept inherent in the provisions of the Treaty relating to competition that each economic operator must determine independently the policy which he intends to adopt on the common market including the choice of the persons and undertakings to which he makes offers or sells.”

64

Perloff, J. 2021. Microeconomics, 5th edn, p. 38.

65

Exempting the passive-reactive companies from measures of public enforcement most likely also limits legal action against them in private enforcement (most notably damage suits). Even if passive-adaptive companies verifiably increased their prices in reaction to the facilitating practice (here PMG) of a competitor, responsibility (intention or negligence of participation in an infringement of Art. 101 TFEU) probably has to be denied due to the remedy problem and the fact that their reaction was forced by the initiator who directly altered the demand functions they were facing. What follows is liability of the initiator for market-wide price increases which might at first glance appear excessive but is similar to damages for umbrella-pricing effects in cartel affected markets, which the ECJ recognized (05.06.2014, C-557/12, ECLI:EU:C:2014:1317—Kone).

66

To the contrary: Lianos, J., Korah, V., Siciliani, P. 2019. Competition Law, 1st edn, p. 428 subsequent using this argument against capturing instances of unilateral public announcements of future prices.

67

Albeit in a different context: Andreoli-Versbach, P., Franck, J.U. 2015. Econometric Evidence to Target Tacit Collusion in Oligopolistic Markets, Journal of Competiton Law and Economics, 11:463, 466: “Rather, antitrust law should capture such instances of ‘unilateral collusion‘only through considering as illegal the unilateral conduct that actively promotes the implementation of a collusive strategy.”.

68

ECJ, 8.7.1999, C-49/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4125, ECLI:EU:C:1999:356—Anic Partecipazioni, para. 118 subs.; C-199/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4287, ECLI:EU:C:1999:358—Hüls, para. 161 subs.; C-235/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4539, ECLI:EU:C:1999:362—Montecatini, para. 125 subs.; ECJ, 4.6.2009, C-8/08, rep. 2009 I-4529, ECLI:EU:C:2009:343—T-Mobile Netherlands, para. 51, 62.

69

See only General Court, 24.10.1991, T-1/89, rep. 1991 II-1034, ECLI:EU:T:1991:56—Rhône-Poulenc and the respective sections of the opinion by Advocate General Vesterdorf, 10.07.1991, T-1/89, rep. 1991 II-869, 921–944, ECLI:EU:T:1991:38.

70

ECJ, 8.7.1999, C-49/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4125, ECLI:EU:C:1999:356—Anic Partecipazioni, para. 118 subs.

71

ECJ, 8.7.1999, C-199/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4287, ECLI:EU:C:1999:358—Hüls, para. 161 subs.

72

See only ECJ, 4.6.2009, C-8/08, rep. 2009 I-4529, ECLI:EU:C:2009:343—T-Mobile Netherlands, para. 51; ECJ, 19.03.2015, C-286/13 P, EU:C:2015:184—Dole Food and Dole Fresh Fruit Europe v Commission, para. 126.

73

ECJ, 14.07.1972, 48/69, rep. 1972–00619, ECLI:EU:C:1972:70—ICI, para. 64/67.

74

ECJ, 16.12.1975, 40–48/73 and others, rep. 1975–01663, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174—Suiker Unie, para. 174.

75

ECJ, 16.12.1975, Verb. Rs. 40–48/73 u.a., rep. 1975–01663, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174—Suiker Unie, para. 27; see also rec. 165: “All these considerations show that Italian regulations and the way in which they have been implemented had a determinative effect on some of the most important aspects of the course of conduct of the undertakings concerned which the Commission criticizes, so that it appears that, had it not been for these regulations and their implementation, the cooperation, which is the subject-matter of these proceedings, either would not have taken place or would have assumed a form different from that found to have existed by the Commission.”

76

ECJ, 14.07.1981, 170/80, rep. 1981–02021, ECLI:EU:C:1981:178—Züchner, para. 13; ECJ, 16.12.1975, 40–48/73 and others, rep. 1975–01663, ECLI:EU:C:1975:174—Suiker Unie, para. 173.

77

Contrary to here: Lianos, I., Korah, V., Siciliani, P. 2019. Competition Law, 1st edn, p. 390: “By referring to various forms of the same thing, “coordination and cooperation,” […]”; Bailey, D., John, L.E. 2018. Bellamy/Child, European Union Law of Competition, 8th edn, , p. 121, rec. 2.070: “Concertation or cooperation between undertakings.”

78

Ezrachi, A. 2021. EU Competition Law, 7th edn, p. 79; Marchisio, E. 2017. From Concerted Practices to Invitations to Collude, European Competition Law Review, 38:555, 556.

79

ECJ, 14.07.1972, 48/69, rep. 1972–00619, ECLI:EU:C:1972:70—ICI, para. 119.

80

See also the explicit understanding of the German Federal Court of Justice in footnote 15.

81

ECJ, 14.07.1972, 48/69, rep. 1972–00619, ECLI:EU:C:1972:70—ICI, para. 64: “Although parallel behavior may not by itself be identified with a concerted practice, it may however amount to strong evidence of such a practice if it leads to conditions of competition which do not correspond to the normal conditions of the market, having regard to the nature of the products, the size and number of the undertakings, and the volume of the said market.”

82

ECJ, 8.7.1999, C-49/92 P, rep. 1999, I-4125, ECLI:EU:C:1999:356—Anic Partecipazioni, para. 117.

83

Faull, J., Kjølbye, L., Leupold, H., Nikpay, A. 2014. In Faull, J., Nikpay, A. (eds), The EU Law of Competition, 3rd edn, p. 220, rec. 3.131.

84

ECJ, 21.01.2016, C-74/14, ECLI:EU:C:2016:42—Eturas.

85

Marchisio, E. 2017. From Concerted Practices to Invitations to Collude, European Competition Law Review, 38:555, 555 subs.

86

Settled case law: ECJ, 19.03.2009, C-510/06, rep. 2009 I-1843, ECLI:EU:C:2009:166—ADM/Commission, para. 119; ECJ, 07.01.2004, C-204/00 and others, rep. 2004 I-403, ECLI:EU:C:2004:6—Aalborg Portland/Commission, para. 81 subs.; confirmed by: General Court, 29.06.2012, T-360/09, ECLI:EU:T:2012:332—E.ON Ruhrgas/Commission, para. 176; previously already General Court, 05.12.2006, T-303/02, rep. 2006 II-4567, ECLI:EU:T:2006:374—Westfalen Gassen Nederland/Commission, para. 101 ff.; General Court, 11.12.2003, T-61/99, rep. 2003 II-5349, ECLI:EU:T:2003:335—Adriatica di Navigazione/Kommission, para. 138; General Court, 06.04.1995, T-142/89, rep. 1995 II-867, ECLI:EU:T:1995:63—Boël/Kommission, para. 60; from the literature see Bailey, D. 2008. “Publicly Distancing” Oneself from a Cartel, World Competition, 31:177; Abenhaïm, M. 2016. Public Distancing and Liability in Cartel Cases: Does Distance Lend Enchantment?, World Competition, 39:413.

87

General Court, 15.03.00, T-25/95 and others, rep. 2000 II-508, ECLI:EU:T:2000:77—Cimenteries, para. 1848 subs.

88

Cf. Andreoli-Versbach, P., Franck, J.-U. 2015. Econometric Evidence to Target Tacit Collusion in Oligopolistic Markets, Journal of Competiton Law and Economics, 11:463, 466: Rather, antitrust law should capture such instances of unilateral collusion “only through considering as illegal the unilateral conduct that actively promotes the implementation of a collusive strategy.”

89

For an extensive investigation, see Pahlen, R., Vahrenholt, O. 2014. Signaling und das Kartellverbot—Öffentliche Verlautbarungen im Fokus der Kartellbehörden, Zeitschrift für Wettbewerbsrecht, 12:442.

90

For one exception see maybe: Dutch Authority for Consumers and Markets (ACM), settlement decision, 7.1.2014, case docket 13.06126.53—Mobile Operators.

91

See again recently: EU-Commission, 07.07.2016, AT.39850—Container Shipping, rec. 35 subsequent, 45 subsequent; German Federal Cartel Office (BKartA), Final report regarding a sec. 32e GWB decision, B1–73/13, July 2017, p. 240 subs.; Irish Competition and Consumer Protection Commission (CCPC), press statement from 20.08.2021, “Motor insurers set to introduce new compliance measures following CCPC investigation” (https://www.ccpc.ie/business/motor-insurers-set-to-introduce-new-compliance-measures-following-ccpc-investigation/).

92

EU-Commission, Official Journal, 14.1.2011, C 11/1 (Horizontal Guidelines), rec. 63.

93

Lianos, I., Wagner-von Papp, F. 2022. Tackling Invitations to Collude and Unilateral Disclosure: The Moving Frontiers of Competition Law?, Journal of European Competition Law and Practice, 13:249–253.

94

Andreoli-Versbach, P., Franck, J.-U. 2015. Endogenous Price Commitment, Sticky and Leadership Pricing: Evidence from the Italian Petrol Market, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 40:31.

95

Andreoli-Versbach, P., Franck, J.-U. 2015. Econometric Evidence to Target Tacit Collusion in Oligopolistic Markets, Journal of Competiton Law and Economics, 11:463, 466; Franck, J.-U. Recht und Ökonomik: Zur Bedeutung rechtlicher Expertise für die Industrieökonomen, In Rehberg (ed.), Der Erkenntniswert von Rechtswissenschaft für andere Disziplinen, 2018, p. 55; Franck, J.-U. Wettbewerbsschutz durch Kartellrecht: Normative Grenzen einer am ökonomischen Anspruch ausgerichteten Marktordnung, In Budzinski/Haucap (eds), Recht und Ökonomie, 2020, p. 235, 246 subs.

96

Andreoli-Versbach, P., Franck, J.-U. 2015. Econometric Evidence to Target Tacit Collusion in Oligopolistic Markets, Journal of Competiton Law and Economics, 11:463, 488 subs.

Author notes

Research Fellow, Behavioral Law and Economics Group, Max-Planck-Institute for Research on Collective Goods, Kurt-Schumacher-Straße 10, 53113 Bonn, Germany; Corporate Development Department, Faculty of Management, Economics and Social Sciences, University of Cologne, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Köln, Germany; Center for Advanced Studies in Law & Economics (CASTLE), University of Bonn, Adenauerallee 24-42, 53113 Bonn, Germany; E-mail: [email protected]; I thank Dr. Brian Cooper for valuable assistance in language editing. In accordance with the ASCOLA declaration of ethics, there is no conflict of interest to report. I have not received any external funding for this research. The paper is a companion article to my PhD thesis, published in German: Rottmann, Preisgarantien im Wettbewerbsrecht 2024, Nomos Publishing, Baden-Baden, Germany.

This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted reuse, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.