-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
John Leventides, Costas Poulios, Elias Camouzis, A discrete dynamics approach to interbank financial contagion, IMA Journal of Mathematical Control and Information, Volume 39, Issue 2, June 2022, Pages 409–442, https://doi.org/10.1093/imamci/dnab007
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
The purpose of this paper is to describe in terms of mathematical models and systems theory the dynamics of interbank financial contagion. Such a description gives rise to a model that can be studied with mathematical tools and will provide a new framework for the study of contagion dynamics complementary to research by simulation studied so far. It provides a better understanding of such financial networks and a unifying network for the research of financial contagion. The mathematical description we present is in terms of Boolean dynamical systems and a linear operator. We relate the properties of the dynamical systems to the properties of the operator.
1. Introduction
The problem of financial contagion in an interbank market is a complex one and many academics studied this problem to understand how bank failures affect the financial stability and to shed light into systemic risk. Studying the financial system as a network is one of the methods to investigate the emergence of systemic risks through the interconnections of the banks. In such network structure, every node represents a bank and the capital flows (loans) between banks are represented by the edges of the network.
The flourishing literature of the recent years has addressed several aspects of the problem of financial contagion. As a result, our understanding of this problem has improved considerably. Many papers have contributed to the effort to reveal and explain the innermost mechanisms that cause or foster the financial contagion (for instance, see Acemoglu et al., 2015; Amini et al., 2016; Caccioli et al., 2014; Cifuentes et al., 2005; Cimini et al., 2015; Cont et al., 2010; De Souza et al., 2016; Elliott et al., 2014; Elsinger et al., 2006; Fink et al., 2016; Freixas et al., 2000; Gai & Kapadia, 2010; Georgescu, 2015; Glasserman & Young, 2015; Glasserman & Young, 2016; Greenwood et al., 2015; Ladley, 2013; Memmel & Sachs, 2013; Nier et al., 2007; Tonzer, 2015). However, the introduction of adequate indicators that objectively assess the robustness of the market and its institutions and are related to measurable features of the institutions is always desirable, since it helps the regulatory system to take targeted actions for eliminating the systemic risk.
The topology of the financial network plays a central role in the problem of contagion and, inevitably, has become the topic of many studies (see Acemoglu et al., 2015; Allen & Gale, 2000; Anand et al., 2015; Bardoscia et al., 2017; Iori et al., 2006; Mistrulli, 2011). Interconnectedness between banks has a two-pronged role: on the one hand it stabilizes the system by distributing funds in an effective way among banks; on the other hand can make the system prone to financial contagion through the interbank linkages. This feature of economic networks is depicted in this characteristic property (Acemoglu et al., 2015): when the magnitude of negative shocks is small, then a densely connected network contributes to the stability of the system; however, if this magnitude exceeds a certain threshold, then dense interconnections contribute to the spreading of the contagion. Furthermore, recent studies have revealed the importance of institutions that may not be very large, but they have a lot of connections (‘too-connected-to-fail’ theory). Their failure could trigger a severe series of defaults (see Battiston et al., 2012; Caccioli et al., 2012; Chinazzi et al., 2015).
Undoubtedly, some of the main purposes of the aforementioned studies can be summarized as follows: (1) to facilitate the assessment of an interbank network and of the institutions of which it consists; (2) to detect the weak points of the system and how prone the interbank market is to systemic risk; (3) to help the regulators and supervisors of the system to take suitable proactive measures when it is needed (for instance, see De Souza et al., 2016; Elsinger et al. (2006); Glasserman & Young (2016); Huang et al. (2012)). From this point of view, it is always desirable general results about the causes or the mechanism of the contagion or the topology of the network (although their importance cannot be disputed) to be accompanied by quantitative methods for the assessment of a particular network and for the suitable decision policy.
In the present paper, we adopt this kind of approach towards the study of the problem of financial contagion. Our aim is neither to describe the sources of financial contagion in general nor to analyse the role of the network structure. Our purpose is to develop a theoretical framework and a generic method that, given an arbitrary interbank network, will enable us to study the transmission of the contagion within this particular network and its reaction to systemic shocks for all possible combinations of initial defaulted institutions. Our ultimate goal is through this method to elaborate various metrics for the assessment of the network and the banks of which it consists and for the measurement of the total damage that the contagion creates. These metrics evaluate the robustness of the network and classify its institutions from the more vulnerable to the more stable. As a consequence, using finitely many numbers, the regulators and supervisors of an economic network will be able to assess its stability and detect its weak points.
In order to achieve our goal and produce the aforementioned method, we appeal to tools and techniques from mathematics. More precisely, we utilize tools from systems theory, complex systems and operator theory. The theory of complex systems initiated from research related to engineering and computer science (see Karcanias et al., 1995). Nevertheless, it quickly expanded to several other areas and in particular to issues concerning financial research (for example see Galbiati et al., 2013). In the present work, we elaborate a mathematical theory describing in detail the interbank networks using ideas from complex systems.
The fact that the phenomenon of contagion and the systemic risk are associated with a plethora of multiple and complicated factors cannot be disputed. For instance, except the interbank lending, financial contagion is related to the existence of multiple different financial contracts, multiple types of financial institutions, the presence of uncertainty in the balance sheet size of financial institutions, the constraints of the policies that could be implemented, the characteristics of the market in which the institutions operate, the stock market performance, etc. Furthermore, socio-economic factors can also create or affect the contagion, for example the unemployment rate, the decline in consumption, environmental disasters, etc. Finally, the fact that all these factors are not time invariant cannot be omitted either.
The extended literature of the past 20 years contains investigations that take into account several of the above factors. Nevertheless, the complexity of the problem of contagion and the fact that different factors follow different rules (for example, some could be described with stochastic models, while others with differential equations etc.) makes impossible the evolution of an abstract mathematical theory involving several causes of the financial contagion. For this reason, theoretical studies usually focus on the most significant factors (interconnectedness, interbank lending, capitals) (see Acemoglu et al., 2015; Amini et al., 2016; Barucca et al., 2016; Gai & Kapadia, 2010; Gandy & Veraart, 2016), and computer simulation has emerged as one of the main tools for analysing interbank networks (see Gai & Kapadia, 2010; Greenwood et al., 2015; Hałaj & Kok, 2013; Iori et al., 2006; Leventides et al., 2019; Upper, 2011). Consequently, in this piece of work, we are not aiming at addressing all the issues relevant to financial contagion, but we concentrate on the more important ones, which actually lay in the core of the economic crisis of 2007–2009. Therefore, we develop a theoretical framework for the study of contagion dynamics that also corresponds to a realistic example. Finally, we believe that this framework could be a model for similar studies in the future, which will combine or focus on other parameters of financial contagion.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows. In Section 2, we model the transmission of financial contagion in an interbank network. We define the contagion map, which plays a central role throughout this work, and we study its properties. This map enriches the powerset |$2^X$| of the set |$X$| of banks with a tree structure. Section 3 shows that the contagion map can be described in terms of Boolean dynamical systems. In Section 4, several metrics for the evaluation of banks and networks are introduced. Section 5 provides information for the calculation of these metrics, while Section 6 gives upper and lower bounds for some of them. In Section 7 and 8, linear operators are used and give further insight to the problem of the transmission of financial contagion in an interbank network. All the ideas contained in this work are illustrated with several examples in Section 9 and, finally, Section 10 concludes the paper.
2. Mathematical modelling of interbank networks and financial contagion
2.1 The interbank network and default contagion
Financial systems can be represented as directed weighted graphs, or networks (see for example Acemoglu et al., 2015; Amini et al., 2016; Cont et al., 2010; Leventides et al., 2019). An interbank network is a triple |$(X, E, C)$|, where
the vertex set is |$X=\{1,2,\ldots , n\}$| and its elements represent financial institutions;
|$C=(c_1, c_2, \ldots , c_n)$| denotes the vector of capitals, i.e. |$c_i$| is the capital of the institution |$i$| representing its ability to absorb losses;
|$E=(E_{ij})_{i,j=1}^n$| is the matrix of bilateral exposures. That is, |$E_{ij}$| stands for the exposure of institution |$i$| to institution |$j$| defined as the value of all liabilities of |$j$| to |$i$| at the date of computation. Clearly, |$E$| is an |$n\times n$| matrix whose diagonal line contains only |$0$|, since banks do not lend to themselves.
The mechanism of the financial contagion is as follows. An institution (say |$i$|) defaults when it fails to fulfill a legal obligation, for instance some scheduled debt payment, or when it is unable to service a loan. The defaulted institution cannot meet its liabilities and create loan losses to its creditors. These losses are imputed to the capital of the creditors, leading to a loss of |$E_{ji}$| for the creditor |$j$|. In the case where the loss exceeds the capital, i.e. |$E_{ji}>c_j$|, then the bank |$j$| becomes insolvent. Insolvency may not necessarily imply default, since the bank |$j$| may be able to find some liquidity to serve its obligations. However, financial institutions are funded through short term debt, which must be constantly renewed and depends to the solvency and creditworthiness of the institutions. Consequently, insolvent banks are extremely difficult to raise up their levels of liquidity and it is generally accepted that inadequate capital levels entail the instability of the financial network. Hence, in this work, we consider insolvent banks as defaulted. Furthermore, we recognize that other scenarios to default may exist, which entail the phenomenon of contagion. From this point of view, this work serves as a lower bound of the contagion.
Finally, in line with various studies, we adopt the zero recovery assumption for shock transmission, i.e. the creditor banks loss all their interbank assets held against a defaulting bank. This assumption is a realistic one in the short run and it has been used in the literature to analyze worst case scenarios (see Chinazzi et al., 2015; Gai & Kapadia, 2010; Leventides et al., 2019).
Summarizing, the failure of one or more nodes of the graph may lead other institutions to default and the shock propagation continues creating a cascade of defaults.
2.2 The contagion map
It should be highlighted that |$T(A)$| describes the first stage of the interbank network after the failure of the banks |$A$|. The defaulted banks |$T(A)$| create loan losses to other banks and a second round of bankruptcies occurs. The new set of defaulted banks is of course |$T(T(A))$| and the transmission of the crisis continues up to the point where an equilibrium set of the map |$T$| occurs, that is a set |$U\subseteq X$| such that |$T(U)=U$|.
2.3 The contagion relation
Since |$A\subseteq T(A)$|, we have that |$A\leqslant ^c B$| implies |$A\subseteq B$|. However, the inverse implication is not true in general.
It is not hard to see that the above relation |$\leqslant ^c$| defines a partial order on the set |$2^X$| of all subsets of |$X$| and hence |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| becomes a partially ordered set. Thus, |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| can be studied with mathematical tools. Furthermore, |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$|, as partially ordered set, can be represented with a diagram: the vertices of the diagram are the elements of |$2^X$|, the edges of the diagram are all the pairs |$(x,y)$| such that |$x <^c y$| and there is no |$z$| such that |$x<^c z<^c y$|. This diagram will be called the contagion graph. It should be noticed that the contagion graph is different from the initial graph representing the interbank network. The contagion graph is much bigger, since it consists of |$2^n$| vertices, and its purpose is to describe the transmission of an economic crisis through the interbank system.
2.4 Maximal and minimal elements of |$(2^X,\leqslant ^c)$|
Our first purpose is to take a closer look at the maximal and minimal elements of the partially ordered set |$(2^X,\leqslant ^c)$|. Recall that an element |$A$| of a partially ordered set |$(\mathfrak{H},\leqslant )$| is said to be maximal (respectively, minimal) if for any |$B\in \mathfrak{H}$|, |$A\leqslant B$| (resp., |$B\leqslant A$|) implies that |$A=B$| (e.g. see Anderson, 1985).
Let us start with the maximal elements. Assuming that |$A\in 2^X$| is maximal, then, since |$A\leqslant ^c T(A)$|, we deduce that |$T(A)=A$|. Conversely, if |$T(A)=A$|, then |$A$| is maximal, on account of the fact that |$T^k(A)=A$| for every |$k$|. Therefore, the maximal elements of |$2^X$| with respect to the partial order |$\leqslant ^c$| correspond to the equilibrium sets of the contagion map |$T$|, that is the sets where the transmission of an initial shock eventually stops.
As far as the minimal elements are concerned, if |$A$| is minimal, then for any |$B\ne A$| we can conclude that |$T(B)\ne A$| (otherwise, we would have |$B\leqslant ^c A$| and |$B\ne A$|). Conversely, if |$T(B)\ne A$| for any |$B\ne A$|, then |$A$| is minimal. Indeed, if one could find a set |$B\ne A$| such that |$B\leqslant ^c A$|, then |$A=T^k(B)$| for some |$k\geqslant 1$|, and thus, |$A=T(C)$| for |$C=T^{k-1}(B)$|, which is a contradiction.
Therefore, we have proved the next proposition.
The following holds.
An element |$A\in 2^X$| is |$\leqslant ^c$|-maximal if and only if |$T(A)=A$|.
An element |$A\in 2^X$| is |$\leqslant ^c$|-minimal if and only if |$T(B)\ne A$| for any |$B\ne A$|.
If the set |$A$| is a singleton, then it is clear that |$A$| is a minimal set. The converse is not always true. That is, there may be minimal sets containing two or more nodes (banks).
A set |$A\in 2^X$| may be simultaneously maximal and minimal. The standard example is the empty set; however, there may be other sets with this property. For instance, if |$A=\{i\}$| is maximal (and, of course, minimal), then this means that the bank |$i$| does not have serious impact on the interbank system, since its default leads no other bank to failure.
Let us examine the extreme case of the contagion maps |$T_{nc}$| and |$T_{tc}$| mentioned above. In the case of |$T_{nc}$|, we have that any set |$A\in 2^X$| is maximal and minimal at the same time. In the case of total contagion, that is the case of the map |$T_{tc}$|, we have that the only maximal elements are the empty set and the set |$X$| itself. Moreover, in this case, every |$A\ne X$| is a minimal element.
2.5 Chains and circles of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$|
When the banks belonging to the set |$A$| default, the chain |$\mathcal{C}_A$| describes the development of the crisis through the network. Two features of the chain |$\mathcal{C}_A$| are very important and should be taken into account. The first one is the difference |$\sharp T^m(A) - \sharp A$|, which shows the total number of banks that are affected after the failure of the banks belonging to the set |$A$|. The second one, which should be considered in connection to the first one, is the length of the chain, that is the number |$m$|. This number is related to the time that intervenes between the initial shock and the point where the interbank system is stabilized.
Finally, it is worth mentioning that no chain |$\mathcal{C}= \{A_1\leqslant ^c A_2 \leqslant ^c \ldots \leqslant ^c A_m \}$| can be a circle, that is we cannot have |$A_1 =A_m$|. There is only one exception, namely when |$A\in 2^X$| is both maximal and minimal. Then the corresponding chain is |$\mathcal{C}_A=\{A\}$| and it is trivially a circle.
In the case of the contagion map |$T_{nc}$|, every |$A\subseteq X$| is maximal and minimal. Consequently, every |$A$| produces a maximal chain |$\{A\}$| consisting of only one element.
In the other extreme case, that is the case of the map |$T_{tc}$|, we have the trivial maximal chain |$\{\emptyset \}$| containing only the empty set, and any |$A\ne X$| gives the maximal chain |$\{A\leqslant ^c X\}$| containing two elements |$A$| and |$X$|.
2.6 Connected components and the tree-structure of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$|
The upper sets |$\{P_A \mid A \textrm{maximal}\}$| define a partition of |$2^X$| in the following sense.
For the upper sets the following hold:
- (i) Any set |$B\subseteq X$| belongs to the upper set |$P_A$| for some maximal set |$A\in 2^X$|, that is$$\begin{align*} &\bigcup_{A: \textrm{maximal}} P_A = X.\end{align*}$$
(ii) If |$A\ne A^\prime $| are maximal, then |$P_A$| and |$P_{A^\prime }$| are disjoint sets.
The proof is standard, however, it will be given for sake of completeness.
For any set |$B\subseteq X$| the chain |$\mathcal{C}_B = \{B, T(B), \ldots , T^m(B) \}$| has been defined, where |$A=T^m(B)$| is a maximal element. Clearly, |$B\leqslant ^c A$| and |$B$| belongs to |$P_A$|.
Each component |$P_A$|, A being maximal, has a tree structure. The maximal set |$A$| is located at the highest level of the tree. At the lowest levels there are some minimal sets |$(B_i)_{i\in I}$|. Then, |$P_A$| consists of the maximal chains |$\mathcal{C}_{B_i}$|, |$i\in I$|, starting from |$B_i$| and ending at |$A$|.
In the case of the contagion map |$T_{nc}$|, every set |$A\subseteq X$| is maximal and forms itself a connected component |$P_A=\{A\}$|.
In the case of |$T_{tc}$|, we have only two maximal sets |$\emptyset , X$|. Therefore, |$2^X$| is composed of two connected components: |$P_\emptyset =\{\emptyset \}$| and |$P_X=\{A\subseteq X \mid A\ne \emptyset \}$|.
3. Boolean dynamical systems
In the previous section, we defined the contagion map |$T\colon 2^X \to 2^X$| and we studied the structure of the generated partially ordered set |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$|. However, handling the powerset |$2^X$| of a set |$X$| is not always easy and mainly it is not suitable for calculation purposes. In the present section, we provide an equivalent description of the contagion map using Boolean dynamical systems.
We now distinguish two cases.
Case I: If |$j\in A$| (which implies that |$j\in T(A)$|), then the |$j$|-th coordinate of the vector |$E_0 \cdot \textbf{1}_{\textbf{A}}$| is equal to |$c_j+\sum _{i\in A, i\ne j} E_{ji}$|. Hence, the |$j$|-th coordinate of |$C - E_0 \cdot \textbf{1}_{\textbf{A}}$| is |$-\sum _{i\in A, i\ne j} E_{ji}$|, and it is non-positive.
4. Quantitative analysis of the contagion
The purpose of the present section is to introduce several parameters that quantify and measure the contagion of a financial shock through the interbank network. Hence they facilitate the assessment of the network and of the banks of which it consists and they help to the better understanding of the mechanism and the consequences of the contagion.
4.1 The contagion vector
In the case of the contagion map |$T_{nc}$|, since |$T_{nc}(A)=A$| for any subset |$A\in 2^X$|, it follows that the contagion vector is clearly the zero vector. However, the other extreme case, that is that of the map |$T_{tc}$| is of more importance. As we will make use of it in the sequel, we isolate it here and it is given in the next proposition.
4.2 Indicators
We next introduce some indicators that enable the measurement of the total damage to which the interbank network is subject and, hence, the assessment of the whole network. It should be pointed out that in this context the term ‘total damage’ does not refer to the total losses of the system at the end of the contagion process, but rather refers to the losses that the system might experience given all possible choices of initially defaulted entities.
Assume that |$A$| is a subset of the set of all banks, that is |$A\in 2^X$|.
(i) Firstly, we set |$\textrm{ind}_1 (A) = \sharp A$|. Therefore, in the case of financial shock, the indicator |$\textrm{ind}_1 (A)$| measures the banks that failures. Clearly, this indicator is given by the inner product: |$\textrm{ind}_1 (A) = \left \langle \textbf{1}_{\textbf{A}}, \textbf{1} \right \rangle $|, where |$\textbf{1}$| is the vector whose all entries are equal to |$1$|.
(ii) Secondly, we let |$\textrm{ind}_2 (A)$| be the sum of the capitals possessed by the banks of the set |$A$|. These capitals are withdrawn from the market after the collapse of the banks of the set |$A$|. It is easy to see that |$\textrm{ind}_2 (A) =\left \langle \textbf{1}_{\textbf{A}}, C \right \rangle $|, for any |$A\subseteq X$|.
(iii) |$\textrm{ind}_3 (A)$| is the sum of the liabilities of the banks of the set |$A$|. In other words, |$\textrm{ind}_3 (A)$| is the sum of the weights of those edges of the interbank graph whose end is some node corresponding to a bank of the set |$A$|. Using the liabilities vector |$L$|, we have the following formula: |$ \textrm{ind}_3 (A) = \left \langle \textbf{1}_{\textbf{A}}, L \right \rangle $|.
The above-mentioned indicators are related to the contagion vector. For the first indicator this connection is given in the next proposition.
Since the indicators |$\textrm{ind}_2 (A)$| and |$\textrm{ind}_3 (A)$| are also written in the form of some inner product, the same argumentation as in the proof of Proposition 4.2, replacing |$\textbf{1}$| with |$C$| and |$L$|, respectively, proves the next formulas for |$m_2(T)$| and |$m_3(T)$|.
5. Calculation of the contagion vector and the indicators
In this section, we examine how the tree-structure of the powerset |$2^X$| affects the calculation of the contagion vector and, therefore, of the indicators. More specifically, it is proved that the contagion vector depends only on the maximal, the minimal and the cross elements of |$2^X$| (defined below).
Now, we set |$A_1=A$| and for each chain |$\mathcal{C}_t$| we denote by |$A_t$| the biggest (with respect to the partial order |$\leqslant ^c$|) element of |$\mathcal{C}_t$| belonging to |$\cup _{j=1}^{t-1} \mathcal{C}_j$|. Geometrically it is easy to detect the sets |$A_t$|, since (with the exception of |$A_1$|) they are those sets of |$P_A$| in which at least two chains cross each other. For this reason, the |$A_t$|’s are said to be the cross elements of |$2^X$|.
6. Upper and lower bounds
6.1 Lower bound
6.2 Upper bound
7. Description through linear operators
The contagion map |$T\colon \mathbb{Z}_2^n \to \mathbb{Z}_2^n$| gives rise to a map |$S_T\colon (e_i)_{i=1}^{2^n} \to (e_i)_{i=1}^{2^n}$| via the formula |$S_T(e_i) = \varPhi T \varPhi ^{-1}(e_i)$|. The map |$S_T$| can be extended linearly to the vector space |$\mathbb{R}^{2^n}$| and a linear operator is produced, which is also denoted by |$S_T\colon \mathbb{R}^{2^n} \to \mathbb{R}^{2^n}$|. The operator |$S_T$| is represented by a |$2^n \times 2^n$|-matrix |$M_T$|. When the vector |$S_T(e_i)$| is written as a linear combination of the vectors of the basis |$(e_j)_{j=1}^{2^n}$| then the coefficients form the |$i$|-th column of the matrix |$M_T$|. Since |$S_T(e_i)$| is itself an element of the basis |$(e_j)_{j=1}^{2^n}$|, it follows that the entries of |$M_T$| are |$0$| or |$1$| and that there is exactly one |$1$| in each column of |$M_T$|.
Because of the method they have been generated, the operator |$S_T$| and the corresponding matrix |$M_T$| depend on the map |$\varPhi $|. If one chooses another |$\varPhi $| (satisfying property (P)), their choice will result in different |$S_T$| and |$M_T$|. Nevertheless, the eigenvalues are not affected by the map |$\varPhi $|.
The eigenvalues of |$S_T$| (and of |$M_T$|) are independent from the correspondence |$\varPhi $|.
Assume that |$\varPsi \colon \mathbb{Z}_2^n \to (e_i)_{i=1}^{2^n}$| is a one-to-one and onto map satisfying property (P). Let also |$\widetilde{S}_T\colon \mathbb{R}^{2^n} \to \mathbb{R}^{2^n}$| and |$\widetilde{M}_T$| be the corresponding linear operator and matrix.
The matrix |$M_T$| is lower triangular.
For any |$i\in \{1,2,\ldots , 2^n\}$|, we have that |$S_T(e_i)$| is a vector of the basis |$(e_j)_{j=1}^{2^n}$|. Let us say that |$S_T(e_i)=e_k$| for some |$k$|. Then, the |$i$|-th column of the matrix |$M_T$| consists of the elements |$m_{ki}=1$| and |$m_{li}=0$| for any |$l\ne k$|. In order to prove that |$M_T$| is lower triangular, it suffices to show that |$k\geqslant i$|.
To this end, assume that |$e_i =\varPhi (\textbf{x})$|. Then |$e_k=S_T(e_i) = \varPhi T \varPhi ^{-1} (e_i) = \varPhi T (\textbf{x})$|. However, the contagion map |$T\colon 2^X \to 2^X$| has the property that |$A\subseteq T(A)$| for any |$A\in 2^X$|. When we identify |$2^X$| with |$\mathbb{Z}_2^n$|, this property means that |$\{l\in \{1,2,\ldots , n\} \mid \textbf{x}_l=1\} \subseteq \{l\in \{1,2,\ldots , n\}\mid T(\textbf{x})_l=1\}$|, that is the number of |$1$|-entries of |$T(X)$| is bigger than or equal to the number of |$1$|-entries of |$x$|. Since, |$e_i =\varPhi (\textbf{x})$|, |$e_k =\varPhi T(\textbf{x})$|, Property (P) of the map |$\varPhi $| implies now that |$k\geqslant i$| and the proof is complete.
The contagion map |$T$| has the property |$T(\emptyset )=\emptyset $| and |$T(X)=X$|. For the matrix |$M_T$|, this implies that |$m_{11}=1$| and |$m_{2^n, 2^n}=1$|, that is these diagonal elements are always equal to |$1$|.
7.1 Contagion vector and linear operator
The contagion vector |$V$| is one of the cornerstones for the assessment of the interbank network and the banks of which the network consists. The next theorem gives the connection between this vector and the linear operator |$S_T$| and the matrix |$M_T$| described above. It also provides us with a method for calculating |$V$|.
8. The eigenstructure of the matrix |$M_T$|
In the present section, the eigenstructure of the matrix |$M_T$| is investigated. More precisely, it is proved that this eigenstructure is closely related to the tree structure and the properties of the partially ordered set |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| studied in Section 2. Our ultimate goal is to describe the Jordan canonical form of the matrix |$M_T$|.
First of all, we know that |$M_T$| is lower triangular with entries |$0$| or |$1$| and at least two diagonal entries are equal to |$1$|. Hence, the characteristic polynomial |$\textrm{det} (M_T-x I)$| of the matrix |$M_T$| has the form |$(1-x)^p (-x)^q$|, where |$p,q$| are non negative integers, with |$p\geqslant 2$| and |$p+q=2^n$|. Therefore, there are two eigenvalues |$\lambda =0$| and |$\lambda =1$|.
Secondly, for every |$i=1,2,\ldots , 2^n$|, the |$i$|-th column of |$M_T$| contains only one non-zero element that is equal to |$1$|. In the case where |$m_{ii}=1$| (that is the non zero element lies in the diagonal), it follows that |$M_T e_i=e_i$|. That is, |$e_i$| is an eigenvector for the eigenvalue |$\lambda =1$|. Consequently, there are |$p$| linearly independent eigenvectors for |$\lambda =1$|, namely |$\{e_i \mid m_{ii}=1\}$|. Each eigenvector produces a Jordan block of order (i.e. the length of its diagonal) |$1$|, that is the |$1\times 1$| matrix |$J=(1)$|.
These eigenvectors are related to the structure of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| in the way that the next proposition demonstrates.
Assume that |$A$| is a maximal element of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| and that |$\varPhi (\textbf{1}_{\textbf{A}})=e_i$|. Then |$M_Te_i=e_i$|, that is |$e_i$| is an eigenvector for the eigenvalue |$\lambda =1$|.
Each minimal set |$B_{j_i}$| generates a Jordan block for the eigenvalue |$\lambda =0$|. The order of the Jordan block is related (but it is not necessary equal) to the length of the maximal chain |$\mathcal{C}_i$|.
In order to simplify the notation of the proof, we observe that the treestructure of |$2^X$| can be transferred to the basis |$(e_i)_{i=1}^{2^n}$| via the function |$\varPhi $|. Consequently, in the basis |$(e_i)_{i=1}^{2^n}$|, we have the contagion relation |$\leqslant ^c$| (|$e_i\leqslant ^c e_j \Leftrightarrow \varPhi ^{-1} (e_i) \leqslant ^c \varPhi ^{-1} (e_j)$|), maximal elements (|$e_i$| is maximal if and only if |$S_T(e_i)=e_i$|), minimal elements |$(e_i$| is minimal if and only of |$S_T(e_j) \ne e_i$| for any |$j\ne i$|), chains and maximal chains and connected components. In other words, replacing each set |$A$| with the vector |$\varPhi (\boldsymbol{1_A})$| we obtain the tree-structure of |$(e_i)_{i=1}^{2^n}$|
Without loss of generality, we can change the enumeration of the maximal chains of which the component |$P_A$| consists as follows:
|$\mathcal{C}_1$| is the maximal chain with the bigger length, i.e. |$l(\mathcal{C}_1) \geqslant l(\mathcal{C}_i)$| for any |$i=1,2,\ldots , k$|. (If the chain with the bigger length is not unique, then we choose one of them.)
- |$\mathcal{C}_2$| is the maximal chain with the property thatfor any |$i=2,3,\ldots ,k$|. That is, when we remove the chain |$\mathcal{C}_1$| from |$P_A$|, then any |$\mathcal{C}_i$| gives a smaller (not maximal) chain |$\mathcal{C}_i\setminus \mathcal{C}_1$|. The chain |$\mathcal{C}_2\setminus \mathcal{C}_1$| is the one with the bigger length.$$\begin{align*} &l(\mathcal{C}_2\setminus \mathcal{C}_1) \geqslant l(\mathcal{C}_i \setminus \mathcal{C}_1)\end{align*}$$
- |$\mathcal{C}_3$| has the property thatfor any |$i=3,\ldots ,k$| and so on.$$\begin{align*} &l(\mathcal{C}_3\setminus (\mathcal{C}_1\cup \mathcal{C}_2)) \geqslant l(\mathcal{C}_i \setminus (\mathcal{C}_1\cup \mathcal{C}_2)),\end{align*}$$
If we sum up the orders of the Jordan blocks for the eigenvalue |$\lambda =0$| that were produced in the proof of the previous theorem, then we can see that this sum is equal to |$\sharp P_A -1$|. Consequently, if we count in the eigenvector corresponding to the maximal element |$A$| of |$P_A$|, we obtain that, for every component |$P_A$|, the sum of the orders of the Jordan blocks it produces is equal to the cardinality of |$P_A$|. Hence, the sum of the orders of the Jordan blocks produced by all the components is equal to the cardinality of |$2^X$|, that is |$2^n$|, and this implies that we have found all the requested Jordan blocks.
To summarise, the Jordan canonical form of the matrix |$M_T$| can be deduced directly from the tree structure of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$|. More specifically, we have the following.
The number of Jordan blocks is equal to the number of maximal and minimal elements of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$|. When a set |$A$| is both maximal and minimal, then it is counted only once as a maximal element.
The maximal elements of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| produce linearly independent eigenvectors for the eigenvalue |$\lambda =1$| and they give Jordan blocks of the form |$J=(1)$|.
Each minimal element |$B_k$| of |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$|, which is not maximal, corresponds to a Jordan block for the eigenvalue |$\lambda =0$|. The order of this block is determined by the length of the maximal chain starting from |$B_k$|. Their relation is given in the proof of Theorem 8.1.
9. Examples
The interbank network described above can be depicted as a directed weighted graph (see Fig. 1).

The directed weighted graph representing the interbank network that is used in the examples. The weights of the edges correspond to the exposures between the banks of the system.
The present paper focuses on the study of the powerset |$2^X$| of the set |$X$|, which contains all the possible combinations of defaulted banks. Since the set |$X$| of this example consists of |$4$| elements, the powerset |$2^X$| contains |$16$| sets. According to the approach of Section 3, each set |$A$| is usually identified with the indicator vector |$\boldsymbol{1_A} \in \mathbb{Z}_2^4$| with zero entries everywhere except the coordinates corresponding to the numbers belonging to |$A$|. Our aim is to describe the contagion map |$T\colon \mathbb{Z}_2^n \to \mathbb{Z}_2^n$|, the induced tree structure of |$2^X$|, the matrix |$M_T$| and its canonical form and to calculate the contagion vector and the indicators |$m_1(T), m_2(T), m_3(T)$|.
9.1 Example |$1$|
As it has been observed, in the case where we have total contagion, the powerset |$2^X$| contains only two maximal elements, namely the sets |$\emptyset = (0,0,0,0)$| and |$X=(1,1,1,1)$|. Hence, the contagion graph |$2^X$| consists of two trees, as it is shown in Fig. 2.

The tree structure of |$2^X \equiv \mathbb{Z}_2^4$| in the case of total contagion.
9.2 Example |$2$|

The tree structure of |$2^X \equiv \mathbb{Z}_2^4$| in the case where there is no contagion.
9.3 Example |$3$|

We observe that there are three maximal elements, namely |$(0,0,0,0)$|, |$(0,0,1,0)$| and |$(1,1,1,1)$| and thus |$\mathbb{Z}_2^4$| consists of three connected components.
9.4 Example |$4$|

The tree structure of |$2^X \equiv \mathbb{Z}_2^4$| for the fourth example.
9.5 Summary
On the contrary, when |$b=\frac{3}{2}$| (Example |$4$|) the situation has improved drastically. Excluding the third bank, the others are quite robust and show resilience to financial shocks. Therefore, the value |$b=\frac{3}{2}$| represents a threshold that the network should cross in order to achieve a satisfying level of robustness.
The third bank is the most vulnerable of the network. Even when the situation of the other banks has improved, the bank |$3$| continues to be at risk. Consequently, this bank should consider additional measures in order to become more robust. These measures may include capital raise or loans reduction or a combination of both policies.
10. Final conclusions: assessment of banks and networks and formulation of policies
The present paper is oriented towards the study of financial contagion in an interbank network system. In order to describe this problem and analyse its parameters, we developed theoretical models that are inspired by tools and techniques coming from dynamical systems and operator theory. However, our ultimate goal is to propose various methods that, given an arbitrary network, enable the assessment of the network as a whole and of each individual institution of which the network consists. As a result, they facilitate the regulators and policy makers in the most suitable decision making. In this last section, aiming at people working in the interbank sector, we wish to isolate and highlight the most important of our results concerning assessment and formulation of policies.
10.1 Assessment of individual banks
Our main tool for evaluating any individual bank of the network is the contagion vector |$V$| (see equation (4.1)). Indeed, as we have commented earlier (see Sections 4 and 9), the values of the coordinates of |$V$| measure the robustness of the corresponding banks. If a coordinate is large, then the corresponding bank is prone to financial shocks. On the contrary, the institutions that correspond to the smallest entries of |$V$| are the most stable and they show resilience to financial shocks.
The second crucial feature of the chain |$\mathcal{C}_i$|, which should be considered in connection to the previous one, is the time that intervenes between the initial shock and the point where the contagion stops and it can be measured by the length |$n_i$| of the chain. The size of this period of time plays an essential role to the strategies that should be considered in order to reduce the contagion effects.
10.2 Assessment of the network
In order to assess the robustness of an interbank network, we have defined three indicators |$m_1, m_2, m_3$| (see Section 4). These quantities take values between |$0$| and |$1$| and measure the level of the contagion in the whole network. The closest to |$0$| they are, the more stable the network. In such a case, the default of each and every bank has limited consequences for the system, which reaches a solid situation relatively quickly. On the contrary, when the indicators are close to |$1$|, the system is very unstable and is prone to financial contagion.
Furthermore, the indicators measure the total damage, i.e. the losses that the system might experience given all possible choices of initially defaulted entities. More precisely, the indicator |$m_1$| estimates the proportion of the affected banks. The second and third indicators measure the capitals that are destroyed and the loans that are not paid back, respectively. Additionally, it should be highlighted that these indicators on the one hand evaluate the network and, on the other hand, make possible the comparison of different networks even though they are completely disjoint from each other.
10.3 Understanding and supervision of systemic risk in an interbank network
Having made the aforementioned assessments, the regulators and supervisors of the interbank network will be able to propose corrective actions and measures (the least possible) in order to improve the resilience of the network to systemic shocks. For instance, the contagion vector assess the vulnerability of each bank belonging to the network and classify them from the most powerful to the most vulnerable. As a consequence, the supervisors are able to detect the weak points of the interbank system and to take suitable proactive measures.
The most important feature in the present work is that we study the contagion in a specific network without using simulation. Our purpose is not to locate and explain the sources of financial contagion in an interbank system in general. On the contrary, our results develop a generic method that in an arbitrary network specifies the properties of the network and the banks of which it consists and their behaviour to financial shocks. Consequently, the ideas and work included in this article actually propose a working methodology for the regulators and supervisors of an interbank network. This methodology consists of three steps.
STEP 1: The starting point is to depict the interbank network that is going to be studied and evaluated. This means that at the particular time the bank institutions participating in the network should be recorded as well as the capital possessed by each bank and the lending relationships among them.
STEP 2: With the methods described in the paper, the contagion graph |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| can be constructed. It should be noticed that the graph |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| is completely different from the graph |$(X,E,C)$|, which shows the lending relations of the banks. The contagion graph |$(2^X, \leqslant ^c)$| is much bigger (if |$X$| contains |$n$| banks, then |$2^X$| consists of |$2^n$| nodes) and describes the transmission of the contagion through the network.
STEP 3: Once the contagion graph has been constructed, the supervisors and regulators of the network, using the methods introduced in this paper, will be able to perform the following tasks:
To assess the vulnerability of any specific bank or of any specific set of banks.
To estimate the vulnerability of the whole network and to detect its weakest points.
To classify the banks of the system according to their vulnerability.
To introduce new metrics and indicators. Clearly, the aforementioned assessments can be achieved through the indicators that are proposed in the paper, which are the most fundamental and typical. However, one may consider new indicators shedding light into different aspects of the network.
To alter the initial conditions (capital, loans, interconnectedness) and to examine the development of crises under various scenarios. Therefore, the regulator will be able to study the consequences of any changes in the initial network and to choose the most appropriate of them.
To summarise, through the present work, the regulator of an interbank network will be able to study the transmission of an economic crisis, to reveal the strong and weak points of the network, to classify the banks or parts of the networks according with their vulnerability and to examine several scenarios.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees for their helpful remarks.
References